Political transition in resource economies

Date01 September 2018
Published date01 September 2018
AuthorSamer Atallah
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12154
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12154
Political transition in resource economies
Samer Atallah
This paper explains the lack of democratization in resource- exporting countries using a two-
period resource extraction model. There are two classes of agents: the elite who own capital and
natural resources, and citizens who own labor. Governmentpolicies are designed to ensure that
the elite remain in power and that citizensdo not have the incentive to revolt. On the other hand,
policies in the democracy case are not constrained by the threat of revolution. Compared to
the democratic case, the resource is over-extractedand the investment is lower. Non-democratic
institutions are the rational choice of the elite.
Key wor ds resource curse, political transition, institution
JEL classification D72, Q32, Q34
Accepted 9 July2016
1 Introduction
Among the top 25 fuel-exporting countries, only Norway is classified as a “full democracy” accord-
ing to the Economist Index of Democracy. Similarly, a handful of countries are considered “full
democracies” within the top countries exporting ores and minerals. This observation is backed by
several empirical studies that found a negative correlation between natural resources, specifically oil,
and democracy, suggesting that resources have a negative impact on democracy (Ross 2001; Jensen
and Wantchekon 2004; Smith 2004; Frankel 2010). Alternatively, it could be that oil is present in
countries where democracy is absent. Most of these countries are located in the Middle East where
authoritarian regimes are the common denominator. The same applies tomajor oil-expor ting coun-
tries in Africa such as Nigeria, Gabon and Sudan. Either way, the question still remains why it is
that resource-dependent countries do not make the transition to democracy,whereas resource-poor
countries make the political transformation. To my knowledge, there are no economic theoretical
models that attempt to answer this question. This is mainly due to the fact that, until recently,
economists have not dealt with democratization with an economic perspective.
The literature on democratization suggests that political transition could takeplace either through
the rise of an economic class that demands more political power or through a political mass that
poses a credible threat of revolution. In the former case, the resource dependence crowds out other
important economic activity in other sectors that are deemed necessary for growth and development
such as investment in humanand physical capital (Gylfason et al. 1999; Sachs and Warner 2001). This
crowding-out effect blocks the channel of modernization, as suggested by Lipset (1959), as it hinders
the growth of a class of agents that is powerful economically and politically. As for the revolution
channel, there is a new stream of economic literature that attempts to explain political transition
Economics Department, American University in Cairo,New Cairo. Egypt. Email: satallah@aucegypt.edu
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 233–255 © IAET 233
International Journal of Economic Theory
Political transition in resource economies Samer Atallah
but does not deal with resource-dependent economies. It is based on conflict between two classes of
agents: a rich minority that actually holds political power and a poor majority that demands political
power.In a non-democracy setting , the eliteuse their political power to set redistributive policies for
their own benefit. Obviously, poor agents would favor a more redistributivescheme which they can
only obtain in a democracy, where policies are, in principal, determined through voting and reflect
median voter preferences. It is important to emphasize that if decisions are solely economic and
rational and there are no ideological preferences for one political structure over another,the elite will
have the incentive to keep the political structure as it is. They might eventually consider “extending
the franchise” if they are faced with a credible threat of revolution. Such a move from citizens has
potentially unfavorableconsequences for the elite as they would lose more than they would have given
away in the case of a democracy. The process of political transition, or democratization, is initiated
when the cost of extending the franchise for the elite and the cost of revolution for citizens are both
low. Incomeinequalit y playsan impor tant rolein this process. The higher inequality is, the more the
redistribution of income will hurt the elite and benefit the poor in a non-democracy (Acemoglu and
Robinson 2001, 2006). One can argue that democratization in Europe during the late eighteenth and
early nineteenth centuries followed this pattern. This literature opens the field for further analysis on
the special case of countries where resource revenues are substantial and are concentrated within a
small group of agents or collected by the government.1Theother interesting characteristic, particular
to resource- dependent economies, is the non-renewable supply of the resource.
This paper is an extension of the literature on democratization. It also uses the insights on the
importance of rent-seeking behavior in resource-dependent economies. When rents generated by
resource exports are collected by a group in power, they increase the value of staying in power and
increase the cost of giving it away (Caselli and Cunningham 2009; Robinson et al. 2006). When
faced by a challenger, the rational response by incumbent governments is to adopt policies such
as patronage and unproductive investment that would increase the probability of retaining power.
These create inefficiencies in the resource and non-resource sectors. There are a couple of missing
elements in the existing political economy models of resource management. The first is that they do
not address the possibility of a threat of revolution by the rest of the population in the economy. The
only threat they consider is the threat of a challenging politician with a competing set of policies.
The challenging politician does not necessarily represent median voter preferences. If the transition
does in fact take place, it is from one dictator to another. The other missing element is that the
policies offered by the challengers cannot be affected by the incumbent government. I address these
missing elements in this paper. I model the threatof revolution conducted by citizens where the main
benefit is to capture a representative part of the resourcerents. This threat is a way to model different
kinds of collective action. It could be a full-fledged revolutionor it could be social unrest that would
negatively affect the elite. Taking the threat into consideration, the elite adopt policies that affect the
whole economy and ensure that the revolution does not take place.
I also make the argument that the type of political institution determines whether a resource
endowment is a blessing or a curse. Decentralized models that explore the institutional nature of
the resource curse seem to dismiss this type of institution.2Institutional quality is modeled as
an exogenous parameter (Mehlum et al. 2006), as the initial number of productive entrepreneurs
1Oil extraction within the members of OPEC is either controlled bygovernment directly or indirectly through government-
controlled firms.
2The empirical literature on the resource curse has found a robust negativecorrelation between resource dependence and
economic growth; see Sachs and Warner(1995, 1999, 2001) and Brunnschweiler and Bulte (2008). For a comprehensive
overview, see Hodler (2006) and Sachs and Warner(2001).
234 International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 233–255 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT