Outsourcing versus vertical integration: Ethier–Markusen meets the property‐rights approach

Date01 March 2014
AuthorYiqing Xie,James R. Markusen
Published date01 March 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12028
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12028
Outsourcing versus vertical integration: Ethier–Markusen
meets the property-rights approach
James R. Markusenand Yiqing Xie
Early analyses of direct investment versus outsourcing focused on the existence of knowledge-
based assets, knowledge being non-rivaled and non-excludable. Ethier was the first to formally
model the consequences of non-excludability for the vertical integration versus outsourcing
decision. Later authors took a different approach, modeling physical capital as fully excludable
but relationship-specific. This paper further develops a model with both non-excludable
knowledge capital and fully excludable physical capital. Results show that vertical integration
tends to be chosen when (a) the technology is relatively knowledge intensive and/or when (b)
knowledge and physical capital are strong complements.
Key wor ds vertical integration, outsourcing, knowledge capital, excludability, property rights,
knowledge intensive.
JEL classification F12, F23
Accepted 1 September 2013
1 Introduction
International business scholars have long been interestedin the decisions of fir ms toproduce abroad
and their decisions on the “mode” of foreign production. Primary among these modes are foreign
direct investment (FDI), in which the foreign producer is vertically integrated into the parent firm,
and a contract or licensing arrangement with an independent foreign producer, now commonly
referred to as outsourcing (OS). The foreign production and mode choice problems are really quite
separate: the decision to produce abroad is a location decision, while the decision to keep production
in-house is an ownership decision. The international business literature is very rich indeed, but it
generally lacks formal models and often has to rely on corporate anecdotes, given the absence of
detailed firm-level data (the absence of OS data persists today).1
Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder,USA. Email: james.markusen@colorado.edu
Department of World Economy and Institute of World Economy, School of Economics, Fudan University, Shanghai,
China.
This paper has been prepared for a special issue of the International Journal of Economic Theory in honor of Professor
Wilfred Ethier. Markusen and Ethier further developed Ethier’s earlier work when they both visited the Institute for
Advanced Studies at the Hebrew Universityfor 6 months in 1989, under a g roupg rant obtained byElhanan Helpman.
Weare/were grateful for this opportunity.
1Dunning (1977) is an early treatment that examines the location and outsourcing issues, though he referred to “in-
ternalization” to mean in-house production, the opposite of outsourcing. Caves (2007) providesa good summar y and
evaluation of international business research.
International Journal of Economic Theory 10 (2014) 75–90 © IAET 75
International Journal of Economic Theory
Outsourcing vs vertical integration James R. Markusen and Yiqing Xie
One thing that comes up repeatedly in the international business literature is that multinational
firms (with owned foreign subsidiaries) are intensive in what we now broadly refer to as knowledge-
based assets or capital. This is inferred from looking at information such as R&D to sales ratios,
the white-collar share of the workforce, product newness and complexity, reputations, product
differentiation measures, and so forth. Physical capital does not tend to be strongly correlated with
multinationality.
Knowledge tends to have two characteristics associated with public goods: it is at least partially
non-rivaled and non-excludable, though we have not seen these terms used in the international
business literature we have read.The first of these proper ties createsan opportunit y for a knowledge-
intensive firm whereas the second creates a difficulty. The non-rivaled property means that, once
created, knowledge can be applied in many production facilities without reducing its value in any
single facility. This in turn gives firms a strong incentive to expand to multiple plants abroad, using
the same knowledge at zero additional cost. But the non-excludability property means that a foreign
firm, whether an owned subsidiary or an arm’s-lengthcontractor, cannot be prevented from learning
the knowledge and either demanding a high return or going it alone.
Twoearly papers (Helpman 1984; Markusen 1984) noted the role of non-rivaled knowledge assets
in determining the location decision, connecting the theory of the multinational with international
trade theory. That is, the non-rivaled property is connected to the location decision. But the question
of the mode of foreign production in these papers is simply assumed to be an owned subsidiary
(vertical integration).
Tothe best of our knowledge, the first formal model that attacked the non-excludability problem
was Ethier (1986). His general idea was that there is a difficulty trying to contract with a foreign
agent: the firm needs to reveal what knowledge it has in the negotiation, but once it does so the
(potential) agent absorbs some of that knowledge costlessly.
The basic consideration working against the arm’s-length [outsourcing] alternative is the fact
that in order to sell its information for its full value, the firm must convincingly indicate what
it has to sell, thereby losing, at least in part, its monopoly advantage (Ethier 1986, p. 808).
The potential agent or contractor needs to see the blueprints, but once he does, the firm’s
advantage is partially lost: the agent can walk away but retaining the knowledge. Non-excludability is
connected to the ownership decision. At least in the field of international economics, there seemed
to be little interest in this topic in the next decade, with the exception of a paper by Horstmannand
Markusen (1987) which focused on the existence and dissipation of reputation capital.
Ethier returned to this topic in a paper with Markusen (Ethier and Markusen 1996). Theirs is
a multi-period model with a new good every two periods. A foreign agent or firm can learn the
knowledge in the first period, and then defect to start a rival firm in the second period, so the
multinational must share rents with the foreign agent in the second period if the contract is to be
preserved. This approach was further developed in Markusen (2001), with closely related papers by
Fosfuri et al. (2001) and Glass and Saggi (2002) appearing at the same time. All of these papers focus
on the non-excludability properties of knowledge-based assets.
A couple of years later, a number of papers appeared which took a quite different and comple-
mentary approach to the FDI versus OS decision. These included Antr`
as (2003, 2005), Antr`
as and
Helpman (2004), and Grossman and Helpman(2002, 2004). These papers beg in with an extreme po-
lar assumption: capital assets are fully excludable physical capital. This assumption is combinedw ith
Williamson’s (1975) notion of relation-specific investments, developed more formally by Grossman
and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990). The two parties to an investment project, firm and
foreign agent, must make up front investment in capital goods, for example, that have little or no
76 International Journal of Economic Theory 10 (2014) 75–90 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT