Optimal divestment time in supply chain redesign under oligopoly: evidence from shale oil production plants

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/itor.12651
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 27 (2020) 2559–2583
DOI: 10.1111/itor.12651
INTERNATIONAL
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
RESEARCH
Optimal divestment time in supply chain redesign under
oligopoly: evidence from shale oil production plants
Farzad Alavifarda,, Dmitry IvanovbandJianHe
c
aAustralian Center of Quantitative Research, Harrington Street, Sydney, NSW 2000, Australia
bThe Berlin School of Economics and Law, Badensche Straße 52, 10825 Berlin,Germany
cSchool of Economics and Finance, RMIT University, Swanston Street,Melbourne, 3000, Australia
E-mail: f.alavifard@gmail.com [Alavifard]; dmitry.ivanov@hwr-berlin.de[Ivanov]; jian.he@rmit.edu.au [He]
Received 4 November2018; received in revised form 12 February 2019; accepted 16 February 2019
Abstract
This paper investigates the optimal timing for the closure of production plants in the context of supply chain
redesign. We consider producers operating under oligopoly and analyze their optimal decisions with the aid
of real options. We contextualize this study in the energy supplychain, where revenue is heavily influenced by
the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). It is optimal to divest from a production if
certain values pass below the liquidation cost. The optimal time to divestis, then, the optimal time to exercise
a perpetual American put option on the total value of the project, where the strike price is the liquidation
value and expenses. The OPEC oligpolistic power is modeled with the aid of a hidden market in a Hidden
Markov Model, since the state of the Markov chain is not directly visible to the production manager. The
reported results can be used by supply chain managers in decision making on production network redesign
in the oligopolistic environment considering present value of plants and cash flows in the supply chain. The
advantage of the modeling approach proposed is its analytical tractability, especially for project valuation
and real-option problems.
Keywords: operations research; supply chain; finance; energy; real option; hidden Markov model; oligopoly; oil shale
extraction
1. Introduction
Supply chain redesign has been an influential research avenue over the last decades (cf. Choi et al.,
2016; Dolgui et al., 2018; Ivanov et al., 2019). Production plant openings and closures belong to the
determinants in this research area. Recent studies (Choi et al., 2016) call for the development of new
methodologies in the given domain byattracting analytical tools from different disciplines,including
finance. In this study, we propose for the first time the use of a real-option approach to the optimal
divestment time in supply chain redesign in terms of production plant closure. There is a substantial
Corresponding author.
C
2019 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2019 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA02148,
USA.
2560 F. Alavifardet al. / Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 27 (2020) 2559–2583
body of work on the applications of real options in corporate finance, operational research, and
supply chain management literature (cf. Mun, 2002; He et al., 2018; Ivanov et al., 2018; Jahani
et al., 2018; and the references therein). In this paper, we extend this work to determine the optimal
liquidation strategy for production plants operating in oligopolistic markets. Due to the significant
economical and financial importance of oil production on global markets, we contextualize our
study for shale extraction.
In recent years, shale extraction has emerged as an alternative source of oil production, signif-
icantly disrupting the traditional petroleum supply chain apparatus. Nonetheless, as a developing
fuel source, the production and processing costs for oil shale are high, given the small nature and
the specialist technology involved. A full-scale project to develop oil shale would require heavy
investment and could potentially leave businesses vulnerable should the oil price drop. The recent
plunge in oil and gas prices have presented many challenges to producers fracking (i.e., hydrologic
fracturing) for shale oil. Many producers have borrowed heavily for capital expenditures, following
a shale oil boom in the United States and low interest rates in the wake of the global financial crisis.
These companies typically pay interest at 10% higher than treasury rates, which puts them at the
verge of bankruptcy, if the low prices continue. On the other hand, in an uncertain world predict-
ing the profitability of production and the returns accrued from investment projects undertaken
is difficult. In an oligopolistic market, such as the oil industry, investment decisions of firms are
directly dependent on the estimated size of production bythe large players. Even a small unexpected
increase in uncertainty may have a strong impact on both market value of firm and expected value
of its future cash flows. For example, between July 2015 and March 2016, the political competition
between Iran and Saudi Arabia, twolarge players in the market, led to an excess supply of crude oil,
which in turn resulted in a drop in value of over 55%. Under these conditions, if a firm overestimates
future demand, then it may be subjected to considerable losses generated by excess supply when
operating revenues fall below production costs.
The oil industry is unique, in that 73% of the world’s proven oil reserves is controlled by the
Organization of the PetroleumExporting Countries (OPEC), an intergovernmental organization of
13 petroleum-exporting nations. Many believe that OPEC acts as a cartel when it sets production
quotas to maintain price (cf. G¨
ulen, 1996). However, others point out that widespread cheating
and political rivalry between members largely neutralizes OPEC’s collective ability to influence
pricing (cf. Colgan, 2013). Therefore, we proposethat the analysis of profitability and, subsequently,
investment (or divestment) decisions must be made considering two states of the market: (a) a
“consensus” state, where the OPEC members can collude and agree on the production level. In
this scenario, members are able to collect monopoly rent by tightening the production level and
increasing oil and gas prices. (b) the “gridlock” state, where the OPEC members cannot reach a
consensus (e.g., November 2015 to March 2016) and oversupply the market, which results in the
low oil prices.
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides a comprehensive analysis
of the literature. The modeling setup is outlined in Section 3. In Section 4, we entail our model
for OPEC’s oligopoly using a hidden Markov model (HMM), including elaborate derivations
for robust filtration and parameter estimations. Section 5 constructs the real-option model and
provides analytical tools for the decision-making process. Section 6 provides a thorough numerical
analysis to highlight the practical importance of our model. Section 7 concludes the paper with a
managerial remark.
C
2019 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2019 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT