On The Chinese Socialist Market Economy And The “New Projectment Economy”

DOIhttps://doi.org/10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.13.4.0502
Pages502-530
Published date20 October 2022
Date20 October 2022
AuthorElias Jabbour,Alexis Dantas,Carlos José Espíndola
Subject MatterChina,new projectment economy,socialist market economy,socioeconomic formation
WRPE Produced and distributed by Pluto Journals www.plutojournals.com/wrpe/
ON THE CHINESE SOCIALIST
MARKET ECONOMY AND THE
“NEW PROJECTMENT ECONOMY”
Elias Jabbour, Alexis Dantas and Carlos José Espíndola
Elias Jabbour (left) is an Associate Professor of the Theory and Policies
of Economic Planning at the State University of Rio de Janeiro. Email:
eliasjabbour@terra.com.br
Alexis Dantas (right) is a Full Professor of Economics at the School
of Economics at the State University of Rio de Janeiro. Email: alexis.
dantas@gmail.com
Carlos José Espíndola is a Full Professor of Geography in the Department
of Geosciences at the Federal University of Santa Catarina. Email: carlos.
espindola@ufsc.br
Abstract: This article aims to show that the Chinese development process over the past four
decades is not a self-explanatory fact. It is a process that may have revealed the ultimate
limitation of the current capacities for interpretation represented by both orthodox and
heterodox approaches. This limitation is due to two objective facts: 1) the transformation
of the “socialist market economy” into a new socioeconomic formation (NSEF), a process
that has accelerated since the financial crisis of 2008—the emergence of this NSEF results
from a series of institutional innovations designed to accommodate a myriad of modes
of production, all of them under the leadership of the public (socialist) sector; and 2) the
continuous technical progress achieved by the state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Following
the successful implementation of proactive industrial policies, the above-mentioned
developments led to the appearance in China of new and superior forms of economic
planning. This process can be understood as the re-emergence of Ignacio Rangel’s “project
economy,” now under the title of the “new projectment economy.” In our view, perceiving
and understanding this change in the mode of production in China, and the theoretical
resources involved in it, represents the greatest challenge before today’s social science.
Key words: China; new projectment economy; socialist market economy; socioeconomic
formation
Introduction
Over the past four decades, the world has undeniably experienced deep transfor-
mations. Financial deregulation, globalization and the emergence of a newly
DOI:10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.13.4.0502
ON THE CHINESE SOCIALIST MARKET ECONOMY 503
World revieW of Political economy vol. 13 no. 4 Winter 2022
dominant financialized pattern of accumulation have drawn the world into a spiral
of instability with unpredictable outcomes. These changes are presenting constant
challenges to international economic governance, and are also raising questions
concerning the very ability of liberal democracies to remain viable almost 30 years
after the fall of the Soviet Union and the old socialist system of alliances. Some
economists acknowledge the possibility that the capitalist system will experience
what Alvin Hansen in the late 1930s called secular stagnation.1
A side effect of so-called globalization is a phenomenon that challenges analysts
from all schools of thought: the Chinese economic rise can be deemed the most
impressive phenomenon of recent times. It is already the longest development and
growth process in history, having overtaken the “miracles” that occurred in South
Korea, Japan, Brazil and the Soviet Union in different periods. China’s economic
growth between 1980 and 2018 was outstanding: the real GDP annual growth aver-
age in this period was 9.2%. For more than four decades, almost without interrup-
tion, the country’s economy grew at rates well above the international average.
Over more than 35 years, the annual growth rate of GDP per capita in China aver-
aged 9.0%, and income per capita (at purchasing power parity) has grown by 36
times, leaping from just USD 250 in 1980 to USD 8,827 in 2018. This process has
been accompanied by high rates of investment, which averaged 36.9% of GDP in
the period 1982–2011, and above 40% from 2004 to the present.2
Since 2013 China has had the largest share of foreign trade of any country, a
performance that has had flow-on effects for practically all other economies.
China has also become a significant capital exporter; its contribution to global
foreign direct investment (FDI) rose from USD 0.8 billion in 1990 to USD 101.9
billion in 2017. The inward flow of FDI to China meanwhile increased from USD
1.4 billion in 1984 to USD 168.2 billion in 2017.3 While until 1991 foreign invest-
ment in China was directed almost exclusively toward export sectors, a high pro-
portion of which were located in Guangdong, from that year on a significantly
higher share of FDI took the form of joint ventures aimed at constructing and
enhancing domestic productive capacity to serve the internal market.
The structural change in China’s economy is reflected in the urbanization pro-
cess that gained speed from 1980, when only 19.3% of the population lived in
cities. By 2018 the urban population had reached 59.1%.4 Although this propor-
tion is well below the average level for developed capitalist countries, the pace of
urbanization suggests the specific challenges of planning and managing the intrin-
sic contradictions of a country where there is a strong cyclical trend toward a crisis
of agrarian overpopulation.
A relevant fact that did not pass unnoticed in the latest Forbes magazine list of
the world’s 500 largest companies, and which indicates a steady if still slow transi-
tion of systemic power, is that for the first time since the list began to be published

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT