On secular stagnation and low interest rates: Demography matters

AuthorStefano Neri,Marco Gross,Giuseppe Ferrero
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/infi.12342
Published date01 December 2019
Date01 December 2019
DOI: 10.1111/infi.12342
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
On secular stagnation and low interest rates:
Demography matters
Giuseppe Ferrero
1
|
Marco Gross
2
|
Stefano Neri
1
1
Banca dItalia, Economic Outlook and
Monetary Policy Directorate, Rome, Italy
2
Monetary and Capital Markets
Department, International Monetary
Fund, Washington, District of Columbia
Correspondence
Stefano Neri, Banca dItalia, Economic
Outlook and Monetary Policy
Directorate, Rome, Italy.
Email: stefano.neri@bancaditalia.it
Abstract
Nominal and real interest rates in advanced economies have
been declining since the mid-1980s and reached historically
low levels after the outbreak of the global financial crisis.
Understanding why interest rates have fallen is of utmost
importance for monetary policy. This paper focuses on one
of the factors contained within the secular stagnation
view: adverse demographic developments. The empirical
analysis shows that these developments have exerted a
downward pressure on real interest rates in the euro area in
the last decade. Building on the projections of the
dependency ratios produced by the European Commission,
we show that the foreseen changes in the age composition of
the population may continue exerting downward pressure
on real interest rates.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Nominal and real short- and long-term interest rates have been decreasing since the mid-eighties. These
rates reached historical low levels after the outbreak of the global financial crisis. Albeit falling
inflation expectations and risk premia have contributed to these developments, as central banks
increasingly focused on price stability, the fall in nominal rates has been associated primarily with a
decline in the real component. After the outbreak of the global financial crisis, monetary policies turned
very accommodative, also by means of unconventional measures, further lowering interest rates.
Understanding why interest rates have fallen is of utmost importance for monetary policy and
financial stability. If interest rates are low in normal times, monetary policy may be constrained by the
effective lower bound (ELB) to the policy rates when faced with a recession (Kiley & Roberts, 2017).
This is one of the key lessons of the global financial crisis: the probability of hitting the ELB is higher
than previously thought, as the real short-term rate consistent with output being at its potential,
unemployment at its natural level and inflation on target (the so-called natural rate of interest) has
International Finance. 2019;117. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/infi © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
1
d
r
B
o
a
a
l
w
o
p
b
r
a
s
e
e
p
f
d
c
i
f
p
o
e
b
i
E
(
p
e
t
H
r
r
r
b
t
l
2
F
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/infi International Finance. 2019;22:262–278.
262
e
g
s
a
d
d
e
.
r
,
s
1
declined. Low interest rates pose risks to f inancial stability by reducing the prof itability and
resilience of financial insti tutions and encouraging exc essive risk-taking (Europ ean Systemic Risk
Board, 2016).
The objective of this paper is to provide evidence of the impact of demographic developments
on real interest rates and other macroeconomic variables in the euro area using a panel vector
autoregressive (VAR) model.
1
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study on the euro
area.
We do not aim at quantitatively and jointly assessing the role of all the factors considered in the
literature.
2
We rather focus only on demographic developments, and in particular ageing, a key factor
within the secular stagnation view. Compared with technological innovation, another potential driver
of real interest rates, which is notoriously very difficult to predict, demographic developments are very
persistent and potentially more predictable. Demographic variables are also likely to be little affected
by business cycle fluctuations in macroeconomic variables.
Two explanations for the decline of interest rates have been put forward in the literature: one
relying on financial-cyclical factors (the financial cycleview), the other on structural factors (the
secular stagnationview). Within the latter, some theories have focused on the structural deficiency of
aggregate demand, others on supply-side factors. We briefly review some of these theories in this
section. We refer the reader to Teulings and Baldwin (2014) and Ferrero and Neri (2017) for a more
extensive discussion.
3
Within the financial cycle view, Borio (2014) and Lo and Rogoff (2015) argue that during the
Great Moderation, financial deregulation, excessively loose monetary policies, and overly optimistic
expectations about future asset returns led to a large increase in the supply of funds, to compressed risk
premia, and to lower interest rates. The correction in the financial cycle after the outbreak of the global
financial crisis, followed by a persistent contraction in aggregate demand and by an increase in the
demand for safe assets, led to a further decline in interest rates. Koo (2014) focuses on the
consequences of balance sheet recessions. The greater the damage to the balance sheet of financial
institutions, the longer it takes to clean them up and for the economy to recover. According to the
financial cycle view, when the deleveraging process ends and expansionary monetary policies are
phased out, interest rates will increase from their historically low levels.
Within the secular stagnati on camp, Summers (2014) and Eggertsson and Mehrotra (20 14) focus
on demand-side factors. Summ ers (2014) argues that the r eal interest rate consistent with full
employment has declined ov er the last decades in the adva nced economies. This declin e may have
been caused by slower popula tion growth, lower-priced capital goods, rising inequality, and th e
increased demand for safe a ssets. To the extent that the nominal short-term r ate cannot fall below its
ELB, the balancing of saving and investment may not be achievable . Eggertsson and Mehrotra
(2014) develop a simple overla pping generation model in wh ich the equilibriumreal rate can be
permanently negative due to excess sav ings. With regard to supply-side fac tors, Gordon (2014)
examines the role of technolog ical innovation and argues tha t technological progress ha s slowed in
the last decades to its historic al average, after a period of sus tained growth between 1930 and 1 980.
However, there is no clear evid ence of the role of productivi ty growth in determining rea l interest
rates (Lunsford & West, 2017). Bl anchard, Furceri, and Pescat ori (2014) argue that the facto rs
responsible for the decline of r eal interest rates before the gl obal financial crisis are unli kely to be
reversed. Rather, they could be reinforced by some of its legacies, keeping the nat ural rate of interest
below pre-crisis levels.
Within the secular stagnation view, demographic developments play an important role. These
trends may affect both the demand and supply sides of the economy. Lower fertility and longer
longevity, which lead to a higher old-age dependency ratio, require more savings for old age, unless
2
|
FERRERO ET AL.FERRERO ET AL.
|
3
263
8.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT