Offshoring, Inshoring and Labor Market Volatility

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12052
AuthorNeil Foster‐McGregor,Johannes Pöschl
Published date01 June 2015
Date01 June 2015
Offshoring, Inshoring and Labor Market
Volatility*
Neil Foster-McGregor and Johannes Pöschl
Received 16 October 2013; accepted 26 February 2015
Using sectoral data from the World Input-Output Database, this paper considers the
impact of offshoring and inshoring on the volatility of employment and wage
growth. Our results indicate that inshoring has a positive impact on sectoral
employment volatility, while offshoring has a negative impact. Additional results
indicate that much of the positive volatility effect of inshoring is found to occur in
countries in East Asia and the EU12, regions that are important destinations for
offshoring activities. Conversely, the negative volatility effect of offshoring is
found to occur mainly in EU15 and ‘Other’ countries, which consists of developed
countries that are relatively intensive offshorers. We also present results to suggest
that firms smooth employment fluctuations by offshoring, and that such smoothing
tends to be concentrated on low-educated and medium-educated workers.
Keywords: employment, inshoring, offshoring, volatility, wages.
JEL classification codes: F1, F4.
doi: 10.1111/asej.12052
I. Introduction
Several studies have linked trade openness to the volatility of output (e.g. Haddad
et al., 2013), with di Giovanni and Levchenko (2009) finding that openness has a
positive and economically significant impact on the volatility of output per
worker growth in a large cross-section of countries.1The presence of such a
relationship is important because studies have found that increased volatility is
associated with lower long-run growth (Ramey and Ramey, 1995) and welfare
(Pallage and Robe, 2003), and affects inequality and poverty (Laursen and
Mahajan, 2005). Theoretically, the argument for a role of openness in affecting
volatility is weak, with little understanding of the channels through which the
effect works. Di Giovanni and Levchenko (2009) discuss a number of channels,
* Foster-McGregor (corresponding author): UNU-MERIT, Keizer-Karelplein 19, 6211TC, Maas-
tricht, the Netherlands. Email: foster@merit.unu.edu. Pöschl: Vienna Institute for International Eco-
nomic Studies (wiiw), Rahlgasse 3, 1060, Vienna, Austria. The authors gratefully acknowledge
financial support from the Jubiläumsfonds of the Austrian National Bank (OeNB). Comments from
participants at the joint CESSA-wiiw workshop held in Vienna in June 2013 and an anonymous
referee are gratefully acknowledged.
1 Recent work also considers the relationship between openness and volatility at the firm level, with
Buch et al. (2006) finding that German firms that export are less volatile than non-exporters, for
example.
bs_bs_banner
Asian Economic Journal 2015, Vol. 29 No. 2, 145–163 145
© 2015 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2015 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Pty Ltd
including the argument that trade exposes a country or industry to external
shocks, changes the degree of co-movement between the trading industries and
the rest of the economy, and impacts upon the diversification of production across
sectors. In this paper, we consider the impact of offshoring and inshoring on
volatility, and in particular the impact of offshoring and inshoring on the volatility
of employment and wage growth.
The ongoing globalization process has seen the increasing frequency of inter-
national outsourcing, or offshoring, of production, involving the contracting out
of activities that were previously performed within a production unit to foreign
subcontractors. Discussion of the impacts of offshoring tends to be focused on
labor markets, in terms of its links to changes in employment, wage levels and
relative wages (see e.g. Feenstra and Hanson, 1999; Foster-McGregor et al.,
2013).
In this paper we move away from this focus on the impact of offshoring on
absolute and relative wages and employment, to consider its impact on labor
market volatility. The expansion in offshoring helps tie industries in different
countries to each other, and this can lead to increased volatility at the sector and
macro level. Such increased volatility may be linked to a number of labor market
phenomena that have been noticed in recent years. For example, increased vola-
tility in labor markets may be an explanation for the increased vulnerability felt by
workers (Alibert et al., 2006), the reduced bargaining power of workers (IMF,
2007), and the reduced opportunities for risk-sharing arrangements between
workers and firms (Bertrand, 2004).
Empirically, a small number of papers have presented evidence to suggest that
offshoring may be a determinant of sectoral volatility. Bergin et al. (2009), for
example, note that employment fluctuations in Mexican maquiladora industries
are twice as volatile as those in their US counterparts, while Comin et al. (2009)
show that although the recent recession in Mexico started later than that in the
USA, it was much more severe. Bergin et al. (2011) develop a model of global
production sharing in which the decisions of firms respond to macroeconomic
shocks. An important feature of the model is that the decision to offshore by firms
in the home market is endogenously determined by comparing home and foreign
unit labor costs. Because home wages are pro-cyclical a boom in demand will
tend to increase the extent of offshoring, with the higher wages in the home
country making it profitable for more firms to offshore production. The reverse
will occur in the case of a negative demand shock. The implication of this is that
shocks in the offshoring country will tend to be amplified in their transmission
abroad. Bergin et al. (2011) identify two main reasons for this amplification
effect. First, in their example of the Mexican maquiladora sector, the foreign
offshoring sector has smaller total employment than in the home country. There-
fore, any given shift in employment from the home to the foreign country (or vice
versa) will have a bigger impact on volatility in the foreign countries. Second, the
direct effect of a demand increase on employment in the home country will be
offset by the indirect decrease in demand due to greater offshoring. In the case of
ASIAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL 146
© 2015 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2015 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Pty Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT