Of leaders and followers—An econometric analysis of equity analysts and stock market investors

AuthorRainer Baule,Hannes Wilke
Published date01 January 2019
Date01 January 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1676
Received: 1 December 2017 Revised: 4 September 2018 Accepted: 9 September 2018
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1676
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Of leaders and followers—An econometric analysis of
equity analysts and stock market investors
Rainer Baule1Hannes Wilke2
1Faculty of Business and Economics,
University of Hagen, Hagen, Germany
2Financial Stability Department Deutsche
Bundesbank, Frankfurt, Germany
Correspondence
Rainer Baule, University of Hagen,
Universitätsstraße 41, 58097 Hagen,
Germany.
Email: rainer.baule@fernuni-hagen.de
JEL Classification: G12; G14; G17; G2;
C32; C53; D82
Abstract
We measure the information content of publicly available analyst consensus
forecasts for 1-year-forward earnings per share based on two well-established
price discovery measures drawn from the area of market microstructure
research. Employing a 36-year sample of large U.S. companies listed in the S&P
100 Index, we compute (a) Hasbrouck's information shares and (b) Gonzalo and
Granger's common factor component shares to measure the relative contribu-
tion that market participants and financial analysts working on the sell side of
the market have in the process of value discovery. We find that although these
analysts are far from leading the market, they have a small but significant share
in the process of value discovery, amounting to 4.6% (Hasbrouck) and 18.0%
(Gonzalo and Granger), on average. This share is persistent over time but varies
significantly in the cross section. We identify the level of analyst coverage and
company age as drivers of this heterogeneity.
KEYWORDS
analyst herding, earnings-per-share consensus forecasts, information share, marketefficiency, price
discovery, sell-side analysts
1INTRODUCTION
Financial analysts act as information intermediaries for
capital markets. Their key tasks are the estimation of
the companies' prospects and the transformation thereof
into earnings forecasts, target prices, buy–sell–hold rec-
ommendations, and so forth, ideally combining strong
economic knowledge with a close connection to the man-
agement of the companies on their coverage list. However,
the simple existence of analysts who improve the process
of price discovery conflicts with the theory of information-
ally efficient markets. According to the efficient market
hypothesis (EMH), every single piece of information rel-
evant to investors is already incorporated into the stock
price. Only for markets that are not alwaysinformationally
efficient, analysts could provide some informational lead-
ership if they were able to incorporate information into
their forecasts that has not yet been priced (correctly) by
the market participants. The degree of such informational
leadership depends upon the relative amount of informa-
tion that is reflected faster by analyst forecasts, compared
with stock market prices.
The empirical question as to the degree to which analysts
are able to fulfil such a role, and thus justify their existence
(i.e., whether analyst output contains information that is
at all relevant to the market), remains open and is still
vigorously debated in the empirical literature. Most publi-
cations in this area apply event studies in order to identify
and measure abnormal stock returns coinciding with the
release of new analyst content. Another extensive strand of
literature formulatestrading strategies that aim to generate
508 © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe IntJ Fin Econ. 2019;24:508–526.
BAULEAND WILKE 509
abnormal returns by exploiting earnings-forecast momen-
tum effects.
In this paper, we propose a new and completely differ-
ent method for analysing the informational contribution of
financial analysts: Adapting econometric approaches from
market microstructure theory, we measure analysts' con-
tribution to the discovery process of the price, or value,
of a stock.1By implementing this method, we can not
only answer the question of whether analyst forecasts lead
stock prices or prices instead lead forecasts but also quan-
tify the extent to which such a lead–lag relationship exists.
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper that
directly determines the percentage share of value discov-
ery between stock prices and analyst forecasts, thus pro-
viding a quantitative measure for the information content
offered by analysts.
We focus on financial analysts working on the sell side
of the market. These analysts are typically employed in
research departments of banks and provide a broad range
of publicly available forecasts.2We measure the infor-
mation content of monthly analyst consensus forecasts
of earnings per share (EPS) as the central analyst out-
put. Assuming a simple relationship between future EPS
and stock value (in the spirit of Gordon, 1959, model),
changes in EPS estimates induce changes in the analysts'
view of the stock value. Stock market prices and such
forecast-based implied stock prices should cointegrate and
therefore share a common stochastic component. On the
basis of a vector error-correction model (VECM) and a
36-year sample of large U.S. companies listed in the S&P
100 Index, we compute Hasbrouck (1995) information
shares (ISs) and Gonzalo and Granger (1995) common
factor component (CFC) shares as measures for the contri-
bution to value discovery.
As we use monthly data, we look at stock-price move-
ments at a low frequency. It is therefore not the simple
speed at which information is reflected in stock prices,
but more importantly the interpretation of information in
terms of the long-term perspectives of the company. To
avoid confusion, we refer to this low-frequency process
as value discovery in contrast to the high-frequency price
discovery.
Our findings show that financial analysts working on
thesellsideofthemarketaremostlypureinformation
followers. However, they nonetheless participate in the
process of value discovery to a small extent. On aver-
age, sell-side analysts aggregate a percentage share of
4.6% (Hasbrouck measure) or 18.0% (Gonzalo and Granger
measure), respectively. These figures vary considerably in
the cross section, ranging from 0% to 33.3% (Hasbrouck) or
0 to 59.3% (Gonzalo and Granger). With the exception of
some periods lasting between 2 to 3 years, the small contri-
bution of analysts can be observed over the whole 36-year
time span.
We find that a company's mean level of analyst coverage
has a significant negative effect on the analysts' IS. This
finding can be explained by a herding argument: Individ-
ual analysts may shrink from opposing a strong consensus
forecast based on a large number of individual estimates.
Consequently, herding behaviour causes EPS forecasts to
be more biassed, and thus less informative in the case of
high coverage. Compared with consensus EPS forecasts
that are made up of only a small number of estimates,
high-coverage forecasts are thus less informative. Another
explanation lies in the covered company's incentives to
provide analysts with high-quality information: As ana-
lyst coverage is basically advantageous for a company, its
management has incentive to attract analysts by offer-
ing them high quality personalized company information
when coverage is low. These incentives vanishas the level
of coverage rises, whereas contrary incentives of limiting
the company's information costs increase. Therefore, com-
pared with analysts of low-coverage companies, analysts
of high-coverage companies will receive less personalized,
and more standardized company information.
Moreover, we observe a weak but (mostly) significant
negative effect of company age on analysts' IS, implying
that sell-side analysts' contribution to the process of value
discovery decreases with increasing company age. This
is consistent with sell-side analysts having advantages in
analysing firms that newly emerged—either from their
own or based on a merger. Here, analysts' informational
edges might result from younger firms and their funda-
mental prospects being more dynamic and less foreseeable
to the public.
The remainder of this article is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we present the theoretical foundations and a
review of the related literature. The econometrical frame-
work and the methodological approach are developed in
Section 3. In Section 4, we first describe our data set and
present some descriptive statistics. We then show our key
results and discuss their implications. Section 5 concludes.
2THE INFORMATION CONTENT
OF ANALYST FORECASTS
According to the EMH proposed by Fama (1970), stock
prices always fully reflect all information available to the
capital market. In his seminal article, Fama formulates
three forms of market efficiency that can be distinguished
by the information set that is available to investors: In the
EMH's weak form, stock prices incorporate only histori-
cal information. Therefore, in a weakly efficient market,
analyst output, which is fundamentally based on current

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT