Nonparametric Evaluation of Economies of Scope in the Context of Technical Efficiency: The Case of Rice and Vegetable Farms in Korea

AuthorKwansoo Kim,Donghwan An
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12059
Date01 September 2015
Published date01 September 2015
Nonparametric Evaluation of Economies of
Scope in the Context of Technical Efficiency:
The Case of Rice and Vegetable Farms
in Korea*
Kwansoo Kim and Donghwan An
Received 20 December 2012; accepted 20 May 2015
This paper provides a nonparametric evaluation of economies of scope in the
context of technical efficiency allowing for non-convexity, with an application to
Korean rice and vegetable farms. Relying on non-parametric-free disposal hull and
data envelopment analysis approaches and input–output data for rice and vegetable
farms from the Korea Farm Household Economy Survey data collected in 2007,
this article examines technical inefficiency and its decomposition under non-
convexity and convexity. Empirical measures of technical inefficiency and its
decomposition results are provided, with a focus on a component of technical
inefficiency associated with economies of scope (i.e. diversification benefits) under
non-convexity in production technology. The decomposition measures of technical
inefficiency include pure technical inefficiency, size inefficiency and diversifica-
tion inefficiency. The results provide empirical evidence supporting size-dependent
diversification strategies, where benefits of diversification are larger for small
farms on average compared to those of large farms.
Keywords: data envelopment analysis, directional distance function, diversifica-
tion, economies of scope, free disposal hull, technical efficiency, size.
JEL classification codes: D22, D24, Q12.
doi: 10.1111/asej.12059
I. Introduction
The concept of economies of scope, proposed by Panzar and Willig (1981) and
Baumol et al. (1982), is a useful tool in investigating the existence, nature and
role of synergies and complementarities between production processes of a mul-
tiproduct firm. The concept has been widely used in measuring gains from
* Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Research Institute of Agricul-
ture and Life Sciences, College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Seoul National University,
Gwanakro-1, Gwanak-gu, Seoul 151-921, Korea. Email: kimk@snu.ac.kr. An (corresponding author):
Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Research Institute of Agriculture and
Life Sciences, College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Seoul National University, Gwanakro-1,
Gwanak-gu, Seoul 151-921, Korea. Email: dha@snu.ac.kr. Financial support from the LG Yonam
Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
bs_bs_banner
Asian Economic Journal 2015, Vol. 29 No. 3, 285–301 285
© 2015 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2015 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Pty Ltd
multi-production processes compared with a fully specialized case in the context
of multiproduct industries, including higher education, the banking industry,
telecommunications, environmental management, the entertainment industry, the
multi-utilities industry and the hotel industry (e.g. De Groot et al., 1991; Ferrier
et al., 1993; Bloch et al., 2001; Beresteanu, 2005; Callan et al. (2001) Weng and
Wang, 2004; Farsi et al., 2007; Shin and Kim, 2011). This approach has
proven to be relevant for some cases, including the mergers of firms
producing different outputs where complete specialization is often applicable
(e.g. Bogetoft and Wang, 2005). However, there might be situations where
complete specialization is too extreme for comparison in evaluating economies of
scope. This is particularly relevant when a production process involves partial
specialization (e.g. Evans and Heckman, 1984; Berger et al., 1987). Agricultural
production provides a good example in this context (e.g. Mugera et al., 2008;
Mariano et al., 2011).
Economies of scope usually motivate diversified farm production activities in
agriculture (e.g. Fernandez-Cornejo et al., 1992; Chavas and Aliber, 1993;
Mafoua, 2002; Paul and Nehring, 2005). In Korea, farms are typically family
owned and run, with the manager of the farm being the head of the household and
family members primarily contributing the labor. Thus, for a small farm, we can
expect the gains from diversification to be closely associated with the joint input
use (e.g. labor and/or land) and/or positive externalities associated with diverse
production activities (e.g. benefits from crop rotation). In addition, in agriculture,
a partial specialization scenario appears relevant in production activities where
farms are usually involved in producing multiple outputs. As such, farms usually
do not fully specialize in one production activity. Thus, a partial specialization
case needs to be taken into consideration in investigating economies of scope in
agricultural production. For example, synergies across production processes
(i.e. positive externalities) and joint input use contribute to such diversification
benefits due to economies of scope.
The concept of economies of scope in the context of technical inefficiency
has received much interest in the literature (Färe, 1986; Grosskopf and
Yaisawarng, 1990; Bogetoft and Wang, 2005; and Cherchye et al., 2008;
Cumminsa et al., 2010; Ofori-Bah and Asafu-Adjaye, 2011). Technical ineffi-
ciency can be viewed as the inefficiency of a firm under evaluation compared
to another among a relevant set of firms. When compared to a set of firms
exhibiting different degrees of specialization/diversification, technical ineffi-
ciency might indirectly provide useful information on potential specialization/
diversification benefits. In particular, when a reference set is comprised of firms
with various degrees of specialization/diversification, a partial specialization
scenario can be incorporated into the evaluation of economies of scope. Thus,
a technical inefficiency analysis with a relevant reference set of firms can be a
useful tool for capturing partial specialization scenarios in the evaluation of
economies of scope (i.e. diversification benefits). This idea is motivated partly
by the recent work of Blancard et al. (2011), where potential gains from
ASIAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL 286
© 2015 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2015 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Pty Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT