Neighbour Effects in the Provision of Public Goods in a Young Democracy: Evidence from China

AuthorPhilip Brown,Xiaobo Zhang,Claudio A. Agostini
Published date01 February 2016
Date01 February 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12057
NEIGHBOUR EFFECTS IN THE PROVISION
OF PUBLIC GOODS IN A YOUNG DEMOCRACY:
EVIDENCE FROM CHINA
CLAUDIO A. AGOSTINI*Universidad Adolfo Ibañez
PHILIP BROWN GeoSource Capital
XIAOBO ZHANG International Food Policy Research Institute
Abstract. Fiscal mimicking and yardstick competition among neighbouring jurisdictions have been
widely documented in developed countries with long histories of democracy. However, there is very
little empirical evidence concerning these practices in developing countries with young democracies.
Using a primary panel of 86 rural Chinese administrative villages that have undergone transitions to
democracy over the past two decades, we show that the neighbourhood effect also exists in a young
democracy, albeit at a lower magnitude than in a mature democracy. Elected chairs of village
committees who have served more than one term respond positively to the provision of public
projects in neighbouring villages by increasing both the number of public projects and the funding
allocated to undertake them. In contrast, appointed party secretaries with more than 1 year of
service are insensitive to neighbours’ performance. In addition, village leaders are strategic in timing
the arrival of public projects to increase the probability of re-election: in the year preceding elections,
both the number and budget of public projects increase significantly. In this sense, politicians in
young and old democracies behave alike.
1. INTRODUCTION
Prior to the 1980s, local officials in China were appointed by higher-level
authorities and answered primarily to these authorities rather than to villagers
(Fan, 2001). However, massive democratic reforms in Chinese villages over the
past several decades may have shifted the objectives of elected officials toward
providing public goods to constituents because popular elections increase the
accountability of public officials and influence the chance of re-election, which
may influence the allocation of public resources (Besley and Coate, 2003).
Empirical evidence shows that local elections have, in fact, affected the level of
public goods provided in Chinese villages. For example, Rozelle et al. (2009)
find that the provision of public goods increases when village leaders are elected
(as opposed to being appointed) because public projects positively influence the
probability of re-election. Similarly, Zhang et al. (2004) find that village elec-
tions increase the share of village expenditures allocated to investment in public
goods. Finally, Wang and Yao (2007) and Martinez-Bravo et al. (2011) find that
village elections increase the share of public expenditures and reduce the share of
administrative costs in government spending, which is consistent with the notion
that elections significantly strengthen the accountability of village governments.
However, Wang and Yao (2007) also show that elections have diminished fiscal
*Address for Correspondence: Universidad Adolfo Ibañez, Diagonal Las Torres 2640, Santiago,
Chile. E-mail: claudio.agostini@uai.cl.
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12057
© 2014 Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
Pacic Economic Review, 21: 1 (2016) pp. 1331
bs_bs_banner
sharing across villages, which may affect the provision of public goods that are
complementary across villages. This result suggests that interactions among
villages may play a particularly important role in the provision of public goods
in China.
The possibility that the fiscal behaviour of a local government is positively
influenced by the fiscal behaviour of neighbouring jurisdictions is well estab-
lished (e.g. Case et al., 1993; Besley and Case, 1995). Although empirical evi-
dence has supported these theoretical predictions, the preponderance of
evidence to date comes exclusively from developed countries with long histories
of democracy, and there are few empirical studies from developing countries and
fewer still from nascent democracies.
We use unique data from a poor Chinese province to provide evidence that
fiscal policy in neighbouring villages does influence the provision of public
goods by local governments. Our results are compelling because in contrast to
several studies undertaken in developed countries (Case et al., 1993; Revelli,
2002; Baicker, 2005; Foucalt et al., 2008), public goods, including projects such
as irrigation, terracing and erosion control, are both fully observable and highly
relevant to the electorate. Moreover, because farmers are usually unable to
undertake such investment privately, these goods are only available when pro-
vided by the government. Finally, due to special institutional features of these
data, it is also possible to investigate different roles in the provision of public
goods played by officials who are elected relative to those who are appointed.
2. INSTITUTIONAL BACKGROUND
2.1. Fiscal federalism in China
China’s governing hierarchy consists of five levels: centre, province, prefecture,
county, and township.1Each township includes a few dozen ‘natural villages’, a
handful of which serve as ‘administrative villages’; that is, designated contact
points between township authorities and villagers. Although these administra-
tive villages are not formally part of China’s governing structure, policies and
other information from higher-level authorities are disseminated through
administrative villages, and leaders of administrative villages are the highest-
level authorities with which most villagers interact.2As such, administrative
villages are the organizing political unit in rural China.
China’s rural fiscal system has undergone four major reforms since the early
1980s. The first reforms focused on the decentralization of the planned economy
in order to incentivize revenue generation at the local level, resulting in signifi-
cantly higher revenues for local governments and lower revenues for the central
government. Facing budget constraints, the central government ‘recentralized’
1Prior to the start of reforms in 1978, People’s Communes represented the primary organizational
unit in rural China. People’s Communes were succeeded by townships at the end of agricultural
collectivization.
2Administrative villages succeeded Production Brigades at the end of collectivization.
C. A. AGOSTINI ET AL.
© 2014 Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
14

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT