Motivations for Loan Herding by Chinese Banks and Its Impact on Bank Performance

Published date01 July 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/cwe.12285
AuthorChung‐Hua Shen,Yen‐Hsien Lee,Hao Fang,Chien‐Ping Chung
Date01 July 2019
©2019 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
China & World Economy / 29–52, Vol. 27, No. 4, 2019
29
Motivations for Loan Herding by Chinese Banks and
Its Impact on Bank Performance
Hao Fang, Yen-Hsien Lee, Chung-Hua Shen, Chien-Ping Chung*
Abstract
This study uses a dynamic herding model that considers intertemporal and cross-
sectional correlation to conrm that loan herding occurs among joint-stock commercial
banks (JSCBs) and city commercial banks (CCBs). We clarify the motivations for bank
loan herding. We find that loan herding by both JSCBs and CCBs results more from
following the behavior of other same-type banks than different-type banks because of
characteristic herding or reputational concerns. Loan herding by JSCBs is motivated
by investigative herding, whereas loan herding by CCBs results from informational
cascades. Moreover, loan herding has a signicantly harmful impact on the operating
performance of CCBs but not JSCBs, which may be explained by the irrational behavior
of CCBs. Our results will help Chinese bank supervisors develop appropriate policies
for handling loan herding.
Key words: nancial crisis, irrational herding, loan herding
JEL codes: G2, G4
I. Introduction
Studies of herding behavior have attracted considerable attention. In psychology,
because of informational asymmetry and the agency problem, a group of investors may
follow one another into or out of the same securities over a certain period; this is known
as herding behavior (Wermers, 1999). Previous studies of herding behavior focused
on the irrational trading behavior of institutional investors in capital markets. The
Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny (LSV) (1992) herding measure is a static indicator that
*Hao Fang, Associate Professor, School of Economics, Qu Fu Normal University, China. Email: hihaoa@gmail.
com; Yen-Hsien Lee, Associate Professor, Department of Finance, Chung Yuan Christian University, Taiwan,
China. Email: yh@cycu.edu.tw; Chung-Hua Shen (corresponding author), Professor, Institute of Banking and
Monetary Studies, Nanjing Audit University, China. Email: chshen01@ntu.edu.tw; Chien-Ping Chung, Associate
Professor, College of Management, National Taiwan University of Science and Technology, Taiwan, China.
Email: thomas6311@g2.usc.edu.tw. This study was supported by the Planning Research Project of Social
Science in Shandong Province of China (No. 19CJJJ09).
Hao Fang et al. / 29–52, Vol. 27, No. 4, 2019
©2019 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
30
examines the cross-sectional dependence of trades within a specic period. Extending
the LSV measure to a dynamic model, Sias (2004) measured cross-sectional temporal
dependence directly. Namely, he measured the extent to which institutional investors
follow each other’s trades over adjacent periods. Recently, the concept of herd behavior
has been extended from institutional investors in the capital market to banks in the loan
market.
The term “loan herding” describes the phenomenon of banks following other banks’
loan decisions in lending to industrial rms. Uchida and Nakagawa (2007) demonstrated
that Japanese banks exhibited herd behavior in the loan market and proposed that
cyclical herding behavior during the late 1980s contributed to the decline of the Japanese
economy. Nakagawa et al. (2012) showed that herding by Japanese banks in business
lending had a negative impact on both GDP and land prices for the following two years.
de Juan (2003) found similar evidence regarding the branching decisions of Spanish
banks. Buch and Lipponer (2006) reported that foreign direct investment made by
German banks in Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
countries represented bank herding. Past research has also provided evidence of herding
by banks in China. Using a vector autoregressive model, Chen et al. (2012) found that
state-owned banks (SOBs) and joint-stock banks incidentally exhibit the same credit
behavior and that city commercial banks (CCBs) exhibit irrational herd behavior based on
reputation. Using data on bank lending to colleges and universities, Zou and Deng (2008)
applied Bayes’ theorem on incomplete information to show that a bank loan decision-
maker tends to follow other decision-maker’s lending decisions when information on the
borrower is lacking. Deng and Li (2012) constructed a herd model with multi-subject
communication and found that herd effects arise from information communication and
imitation behavior among agents, which can generate bank runs. However, these studies
did not use the dynamic herding model that considers intertemporal and cross-sectional
correlation or examine the following behavior among banks in lending. Therefore, it is
worth combining these approaches to conduct further analysis.
In this paper, we extend the dynamic herding model in capital markets to explore the
existence of intertemporal loan herding among banks. Although Uchida and Nakagawa
(2007) examined the cross-sectional dependence of lending positions among banks
within a single period, the herding model of a single period cannot reveal the following
behavior of banks in lending; only an intertemporal herding model can clarify whether
banks follow the loan behavior of other banks. Sias (2004) proposed an intertemporal
herding model and decomposed the cross-sectional correlation of institutional trading
into institutions following their own trades (own cascades), institutions following
the trades of other institutions of the same type (same-type herding) and institutions

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT