Misreporting trade: Tariff evasion, corruption, and auditing standards

AuthorDerek Kellenberg,Arik Levinson
Date01 February 2019
Published date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12363
106
|
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ . 2019;27:106–129.
1 | INTRODUCTION
News stories about misreported trade periodically surface in the business press.1 A recent UN report
claimed that a large share—67 percent in some cases—of exports goes unreported (UNCTAD, 2016).
Common themes in these stories include tariff and tax evasion, corruption, regulatory enforcement,
and firms and organizations spanning countries at different levels of economic development. In this
paper, we show that this type of trade misreporting is widespread and varies systematically not only
with tariffs, but also with country characteristics such as economic development, domestic taxes, cor-
ruption, and participation in regional trade agreements (RTAs).
The importance of tariff evasion has not gone unnoticed by economists. Bhagwati (1964) first
wrote about the phenomenon more than 50 years ago, showing that in Turkish trade data the gap
between reports by importers and exporters was correlated with tariffs and import controls. More re-
cently, Fisman and Wei (2004) found that the gap between China’s reported imports from Hong Kong
and Hong Kong’s reported exports to China was larger for industries facing higher Chinese tariffs.
Subsequent papers have examined exports from Germany to 10 transition economies, imports to India,
direct exports from China to the United States, trade between the United States and Canada, imports to
Received: 27 February 2018
|
Revised: 22 May 2018
|
Accepted: 27 May 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12363
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Misreporting trade: Tariff evasion, corruption, and
auditing standards
Derek Kellenberg1
|
Arik Levinson2,3
1Department of Economics, University of
Montana, Missoula, Montana, USA
2Department of Economics, Georgetown
University, Washington, DC, USA
3NBER, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA
Correspondence
Derek Kellenberg, University of Montana, 32
Campus Dr., Missoula, MT 59812, USA.
Email: Derek.Kellenberg@mso.umt.edu
Abstract
Official international trade statistics report commerce be-
tween every pair of countries twice: once for the importing
country and once for the exporter. In principle, the two
values differ only by transport costs, but as has long been
recognized, they also differ systematically with product‐
level tariffs. We aggregate across products to construct a
dataset of annual aggregate bilateral trade, separately for
the importer and exporter reports. With these data, we
show that the reporting differences also vary systemati-
cally with country characteristics aside from tariffs: in-
comes, auditing standards, corruption, and trade
agreements.
|
107
KELLENBERG aNd LEVINSON
Kenya, Mauritius, and Nigeria, and most recently, Tanzanian imports from three developing country
trading partners.2 Although global assessments are scarce, one recent study estimated that in 2012,
more than U.S.$729 billion flowed out of developing countries as the result of trade mis‐invoicing and
tariff evasion (Kar & Spanjers, 2014).
Such reports mostly confirm the Fisman and Wei result that higher tariff rates lead to more tariff
evasion for the samples of countries studied. Like Fisman and Wei, they all identify evasion by com-
paring product‐level tariffs with product‐level trade data reported by exporters and importers between
select pairs of countries. As a result, even though the combined body of evidence suggests that higher
tariffs lead to more misreporting, the results are not generalizable beyond the specific sets of countries
examined. We do not really know the extent to which trade misreporting occurs across a broader set of
countries or goods, or whether it is more prevalent among rich or poor countries.
More importantly, the focus on tariff evasion disregards other country characteristics that may reward
or penalize firms for misreporting trade. Many of these, like income taxes, corruption, accounting stan-
dards, and capital controls, do not vary across industries within a country but do vary across countries
and over time. So their effects on misreported trade cannot be identified using isolated pairs of countries,
and disaggregated product level data provides little in return as national level variables do not vary at the
product level. A large panel of trade data and country characteristics, like the one we have assembled
for this project, is necessary to identify the effects of these country characteristics on misreported trade.
We begin by describing a model in which firms or countries choose how much to misreport their
imports or exports. Those misreports are functions of characteristics such as tariffs, corruption, taxes,
and the strength of auditing and accounting standards. We then use that model, along with a simple
accounting identity, to estimate the effects of those country characteristics on the gap between total
reported exports and imports among pairs of countries, using data on annual trade among 126 coun-
tries from 2002 to 2012.
Our approach using aggregate trade, as opposed to the industry‐by‐industry measures used by
Fisman and Wei (2004) and others, does come with a few trade‐offs. The aggregate approach cannot
identify trade misreporting that results from misclassifying products, say from high‐tariff to low‐tariff
categories, because those misreports are netted out in the aggregate.3 What we observe is pure mis-
reporting: cases where firms have reported to trade authorities a value different from the true value
transacted. In this sense, our analysis should be viewed as a conservative estimate of overall trade
misreporting.
This country‐level approach also measures tariffs using an average rate applied to all products by
each country, possibly introducing a degree of aggregation bias into the estimates of tariff evasion,
but our results are similar whether we use trade‐weighted average tariffs or simple averages of tariff
rates. More importantly, economists have been estimating tariff evasion using product‐level data for
many years. Our focus is elsewhere, on country characteristics that do not vary across products, have
not been studied before, and cannot be identified except at the country level.
In return, our aggregated approach has several advantages. First, by examining aggregate trade
among many countries, we are able to estimate the effects of policy‐relevant country characteris-
tics other than tariffs. These include auditing and accounting standards,4 corruption, participation in
RTAs, and other domestic tax rates. Second, by netting out misclassification through aggregation and
focusing on pure misreporting effects, we avoid difficult empirical challenges associated with disen-
tangling the two in industry‐level analyses. Third, when we do examine tariffs, our empirical strategy
allows us to estimate their average effect on misreporting across a wide variety of importing and
exporting countries. Finally, by aggregating across industries and using country variables as proxies
for misreports, we account for the potential endogeneity of true unobserved trade volumes and those
misreports.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT