Managing Capital Inflows Indirectly? On the Determinants of Monetary Sterilization with Reference to East Asia

Published date01 May 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12265
Date01 May 2017
AuthorTony Cavoli
Managing Capital Inflows Indirectly? On the
Determinants of Monetary Sterilization with
Reference to East Asia
Tony Cavoli*
Abstract
This paper derivesa time-varying sterilization coefficient to examine thosefactors that determine the extent
to which central banks might engage in monetary sterilization. There appear to be good reasons to do so:
Sterilization neutralizes the monetary impact of reserve accumulation, which is an endogenous consequence
of sustained capitalinflows under some degree of management of exchange rates. A pooled sampleof Asian
economies incorporating Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand, for
1994–2012 is employed. We find that this method does help to directlyuncover the determinants of steriliza-
tion, and while capital inflows do not appear to influence the sterilization directly, there is substantial evi-
dence to suggest itdoes so indirectly—particularlythrough domestic interest rates.
1. Introduction
The monetary and financial systems and arrangements in emerging economies are still
for the most part centered around the existence of high capital mobility, managed
exchange rate regimes, and the resultant accumulation of foreign reserves (Cavoli and
Rajan, 2009). As such, it has long been held that the use of sterilized foreign exchange
intervention remains a viable policy choice for monetary authorities.
This paper, then, examines the extent and determinants of monetary sterilization
using a sample of six east and southeast Asian economies, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia,
the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand for the period 1994–2012. These countries are
chosen because they are widely known to have engaged in sterilized intervention for a
very long time. Cavoli and Rajan (2006) report that five of the six counties reported
here (minus Singapore) possess very high levels of sterilization before the Asian Crisis.
Ouyang, Rajan and Willett (2008) also report high sterilization post-crisis. Specifically,
why might these countries engage in sterilization? First, authorities use sterilization
because they wish to neutralize the monetary impacts of reserve accumulation
(Villafuerte and Yap, 2015).
1
IMF (2014) report that, while not of the same magnitude
as larger economies in the region, the Asian economies samples in this paper possess a
substantial desire to continually accumulate reserves. This can be observed in Figure
1, where the annual percentage change in official reserve assets for each nation in this
study is reported. With the exception of 1997 and 2008—the periods corresponding to
the Asian and Global crises, respectively, the boxes appearing above the zero line
reveal that reserves are indeed accumulating for each country—significantly so for
2007 and 2010.
*Cavoli: UniSA Business School, University of South Australia, Adelaide, Australia. E-mail: tony.
cavoli@unisa.edu.au
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Review of International Economics, 25(2), 262–278, 2017
DOI:10.1111/roie.12265
A second, and related, justification for the use of sterilization is that the policy is
used to offset the reserve impacts of foreign capital inflows (Villafuerte and Yap,
2015; Kawai and Lamberte, 2008). High and sustained capital inflows have been pres-
ent in Asia since the early 1990’s (see IMF, 2011). More recently, from Figure 2, we
can see that the growth of capital inflows for each country in our sample has increased,
not only overall but in almost all of the components of capital inflow, viz FDI, portfo-
lio and bank based inflows.
2
Third (and also related), sterilization can be employed to regain control of the
domestic supply of money such that a regime of managed exchange rates can be main-
tained in the face of high capital mobility. We can see from Table 1 that there is evi-
dence of a degree of fixity among exchange rate regimes in the region—especially in
the case of Malaysia and Singapore. Indonesia and Thailand have managed regimes in
the middle part of the sample and Korea and the Philippines present a degree of flexi-
bility in their exchange rate arrangements.
3
There is extensive evidence to suggest that
Asian nations have employed, to varying extents, a degree of systematic management
of their exchange rates since a period of flexibility during the Asian crisis leading to
most re-employing de facto US dollar pegs in that period (Kawai and Pontines, 2014;
Cavoli and Rajan, 2009). Further, the evidence among certain measures of de facto
exchange rate systems for the countries sampled suggests that they actually exhibited
greater fixity (especially to the USD) than presented under the IMF definitions (see
Kawai and Pontines, 2014). As such, the presence of managed exchange rate mecha-
nisms imply the possibility of sterilized intervention. McCauley (2006) states that steri-
lization is part of the suite of macro-financial policies designed in part for the purposes
of exchange rate stabilization. Kawai and Lamberte (2008) provide that such interven-
tion is employed to soak up excess liquidity brought about by foreign exchange inter-
ventions for Korea.
4
For the most part, the rationale for employing sterilization is the broadly same for
each of these countries. Each have accumulated substantial holdings of foreign
reserves, and its associated monetary impact, in the face of managed currency regimes
and high capital inflow. But which of these variables (reserves, capital inflows,
Figure 1. Official Reserve Assets (yearly % change—Excl Gold) 2005–12 [Color fig-
ure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Source: Author calculations using World Development Indicators.
DETERMINANTS OF MONETARY STERILIZATION 263
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT