Making small firms happy? The heterogeneous effect of trade facilitation measures

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12463
Date01 August 2020
Published date01 August 2020
Rev Int Econ. 2020;28:565–598. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie
|
565
© 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Successful exporting implies a good knowledge and understanding of the destination country’s rules
and regulations. The exporter is required to supply the correct documentation, comply with customs
procedures, and be subject to clearance and inspections. Lack of knowledge or uncertainty on the
outcome of the exact procedures can result in the product not complying with the importing coun-
try’s regulations, and then in the firm facing the costs of rejection at the border of the targeted coun-
try. Hence, in addition to the cost of acquiring information about the rules and regulations in the
Received: 15 January 2019
|
Revised: 4 December 2019
|
Accepted: 11 December 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12463
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Making small firms happy? The heterogeneous
effect of trade facilitation measures
LionelFontagné1
|
GianlucaOrefice2
|
RobertaPiermartini3
1PSE, Université Paris I and CEPII, Paris,
France
2CEPII, Paris, France
3ERSD, WTO, Geneva, Switzerland
Correspondence
Lionel Fontagné, Centre d’Economie de
la Sorbonne, 106-112 Bd de l’Hôpital,
F-75647 Paris Cedex 13.
Email: lionel.fontagne@univ-paris1.fr
Abstract
The different facets of trade facilitation may impact het-
erogeneously exporters of different size and productivity.
Using the cross-sectional variation in procedures at the
border, we identify how red tape affects trade through the
extensive and/or the intensive margin and show that small
and large exporters are affected differently. We observe that
while information availability benefits both small and large
exporters, other measures like advance ruling, appeal proce-
dures and the automation of border formalities tend to favor
large exporters. This result suggests that trade facilitation
policies affect exporters through channels other than simply
the fixed or variable cost component of the red tape barriers.
Beyond affecting the size and composition of trade flows,
uncertainty about the conditions of crossing borders plays
an important role in shaping the demography of exporters
across different destinations.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F13; F14
566
|
FONTAGNÉ eT Al.
destination market, which is product–destination specific, there are the costs in terms of time and
uncertainty of delivery linked to the import/export procedure.
These trade frictions are sizable and are frequently complained about in surveys of exporters: cum-
bersome and lengthy administrative procedures at home and abroad cumulate, and represent an im-
portant component of trade cost (Anderson & van Wincoop, 2004). Lengthy shipping times (including
long delays at the border) can imply depreciation costs such as literal spoilage and technological
obsolescence, for example, in the case of consumer electronics (Hummels & Schaur, 2013).1
Delays
in getting goods from origin to destination hinder exports more than do foreign tariffs: the average
tariff applied to imports by sub-Saharan Africa is 11.2%, whereas the tariff equivalent for delay cost
is 25.6%.2
Of these costs, the highest portion is due to administrative procedures. Djankov, Freund,
and Pham (2010) claim that 75% of delays to shipping containers between the origin and destination
countries are due to bureaucracy: customs procedures, tax procedures, clearance, and inspections.
Hornok and Koren (2015) using Spanish shipment-level export data, show that a 50% reduction in per-
shipment administrative costs corresponds to a 9% points reduction in the tariff. Carballo, Graziano,
Schaur, and Volpe-Martincus (2017) use detailed import processing data from Peru and estimate a
21% tariff equivalent of border processing cost.
Firms of different size are plausibly affected heterogeneously by these trade frictions: theory sug-
gests different mechanisms through which trade frictions affect trade and margins of trade by firms’
size. First, in a standard heterogeneous firm model of trade with constant elasticity of substitution
(CES) preferences, a reduction in the fixed costs of export allows less productive firms to enter the
export market (Chaney, 2008; Melitz, 2003). Thus, trade facilitation measures reducing fixed costs
to trade should have a positive effect on margins of trade through the entry of small (less productive)
exporters. This class of models predicts no differential effect on the intensive margin of individual
exporters when the variable costs of trade fall. Second, departing from the classical CES preferences
framework and allowing for firm-specific entry cost, Arkolakis (2010) predicts that when trade costs
increase, trade shares are reallocated away from small firms because sales’ elasticity with respect to
variable trade costs is decreasing in firm size. Finally, a recent strand of literature is shedding a new
light on the impact of border-related trade costs on heterogenous exporters. Focusing on the political
economy of red tape, Maggi, Mrazova, and Neary (2018) show that red tape barriers are used to choke
trade in some goods, if the realized political weight for these products is high. Interestingly, this effect
is not driven by a fixed-cost component of red tape, but generated by a nonconvexity in the government
optimization problem. Their model predicts that large firms may be more affected by red tape than
small firms, even on the extensive margin. Focusing on the uncertainty related to the procedures of
crossing the border, Carballo etal. (2017) show that large firms are more elastic to border processing
time because they manage more complicate supply chains and/or systems of shipments and thus gain
relatively more from fast processing times. In the same vein, DeSousa, Disdier, and Gaigné (2016)
argue that large and most productive firms are more exposed to uncertainty: an increase in the volatil-
ity of foreign demand induces the reallocation of market shares from the most to the least productive
exporters. All in all, rather than simply affecting unevenly trade flows of different size,3
such trade
frictions might affect differently exporters of different size. Such hypothesis is the one explored here.
Considering these complex mechanisms, whether the trade costs in terms of time and uncertainty
at the border affect differently exporters of different size is an empirical issue. The identification is
not an easy task for three reasons. First, we lack systematic information on procedures at the border
of importing countries, as opposed to information on tariff duties. How long does it take, and how
uncertain is it to enter a product in a certain market? Outcome-based measures taken from the Doing
Business indicators of the World Bank have often been used in the literature,4
but going deeper in
the details of the exact procedures to cross the border and the associated degree of uncertainty about
|
567
FONTAGNÉ eT Al.
whether a good is allowed to go through (and at what conditions) is worth an investigation. This
paper uses the data on procedures required to cross the border collected in relation with the Trade
Facilitation Agreement (TFA) to study the impact of time and uncertainty at the border on exporters
of different size.5
Trade facilitation indeed reduces the fixed and/or the variable export costs, but also
the uncertainty in the processing time at the border and in the outcome of the procedures. Formalities,
requirements and custom inspections have to be met each time a shipment crosses a border, and the
related uncertainty represents an additional cost for the exporters. We use here the detailed evidence
collected by the OECD (Trade Facilitation Indicators: TFIs in the following) on information availabil-
ity, involvement in trade community, advance rulings, appeal procedures, formalities, documentation,
and procedures in each importing country (dataset OECD, 2018; Moïsé, Orliac, & Minor, 2011)6
The
second difficulty is to observe the impact of TFIs on firms, rather than on aggregate trade flows. To
proceed, we combine data on TFI with transaction level data for the universe of French exporting
firms (export participation, number of products exported, value of product–destination exports) from
the French Customs. The third difficulty is to properly assess the impact of TFI on firms of different
size, instead of trade flows of different size. The main contribution of the present paper is therefore
testing the effect of different determinants of time required, and uncertainty faced, to cross the bor-
der, on the margins of trade of heterogeneous exporters, here grouped by size bins. Using a quantile
regression, we contrast this evidence with the absence of a nonlinear impact of TFI on transactions of
different size of a given exporter.
Importantly, while existing literature at the firm level has looked at how delays at custom in the
exporting country affect firms’ export behavior (Volpe-Martincus, Carballo, & Graziano, 2015), we
are the first to estimate how time and uncertainty at the border of the importing country affect the
behavior of small and large exporters. We do this for a range of measures that not only affect the time
to cross the border, but also account for increased certainty of rules for exporters (e.g., rules that give
an exporter the right to appeal the decisions of the customs at destination).
Our key finding is that all trade facilitation measures have a positive effect on trade of large firms.
We also find a positive effect on trade of small firms but only for the provisions that facilitate the avail-
ability of information (information and forms publicly available and easily accessible on the internet).
In contrast, involvement of the trade community, right to appeal, advance rulings, or automation pro-
cedures—all measures reducing uncertainty in the outcome of the border procedures—benefit only
large exporters. These findings downplay the usual conclusions regarding the expected benefits of
small firms from reducing red tape. We find evidence (somehow) compatible with firm selection ef-
fects only for measures that foster the flow of information between countries. Results concerning other
provisions are not compatible with a firm selection mechanism. This supports the view that red tape
measures impact trade mainly through their effect on uncertainty (Carballo etal., 2017) or because, by
their nature, they are used for political reasons to choke trade (Maggi etal., 2018).
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present Materials and Methods,
we discuss measures of the TFA and we show how the TFIs constructed by the OECD can be mobi-
lized; we also present the administrative data on the universe of French exporters used to “reveal” the
differentiated impact of the trade facilitation measures on firms of different sizes and capabilities; we
finally present the estimation strategy. Results are discussed in Section 3. Section 4 concludes.
2
|
DATA AND EMPIRICAL STRATEGY
Five indexes based on TFI indicators are used in the present paper: Information Availability,
Involvement in Trade Community, Advance Rulings, Appeal Procedures and Formalities Document,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT