A larger country sets a lower optimal tariff

Published date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12391
AuthorTakumi Naito
Date01 May 2019
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:643–665.
|
643wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie
1
|
INTRODUCTION
It is widely believed among trade economists that an optimal tariff for a large country is positive, and
that a larger country sets a higher optimal tariff. Based on two‐country, two‐good trade models, Kennan
and Riezman (1988) and Syropoulos (2002) verify the latter statement, and even show that a sufficiently
larger country can win a tariff war in that its welfare under the Nash equilibrium of a tariff setting game
is higher than under the global free trade.1 More recently, the optimal tariff problem is reconsidered
in the Dornbusch–Fischer–Samuelson (1977) (DFS henceforth) Ricardian model with a continuum of
goods: Opp (2010) and Costinot, Donaldson, Vogel, and Werning (2015) confirm that the optimal tariffs
are positive and uniform across imported goods, provided that export taxes are unavailable. Moreover,
Opp (2010) demonstrates that a country’s uniform optimal tariff is increasing in its productivity adjusted
size including its absolute advantage parameter and labor endowment. This tempts us to conclude that
the beginning two statements are theoretically robust in a wide class of models.2
Received: 16 November 2017
|
Revised: 27 November 2018
|
Accepted: 20 December 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12391
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
A larger country sets a lower optimal tariff
TakumiNaito
Faculty of Political Science and
Economics,Waseda University, Tokyo,
Japan
Correspondence
Takumi Naito, Faculty of Political Science
and Economics, Waseda University,
1‐6‐1 Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku‐ku, Tokyo
169‐8050, Japan.
Email: tnaito@waseda.jp
Funding information
I acknowledge Japan Society for the
Promotion of Science (#25380336) and
Research Institute of Economy, Trade and
Industry for financial support
Abstract
We develop a new optimal tariff theory that is consistent
with the fact that a larger country sets a lower tariff. In our
dynamic Dornbusch–Fischer–Samuelson Ricardian model,
the long‐run welfare effects of a rise in a country’s tariff
consist of the direct revenue, indirect revenue, and growth
effects. Based on this welfare decomposition, we obtain two
main results. First, the optimal tariff of a country is positive.
Second, the optimal tariff of a country is likely to be de-
creasing in its absolute advantage parameter, implying that
a larger (i.e., more technologically advanced) country sets a
lower optimal tariff.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F13, F43
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution‐NonCommercial‐NoDerivs License, which permits use and
distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, the use is non‐commercial and no modifications or adaptations are
made.
© 2019 The Authors Review of International Economics Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd
644
|
NAITO
In fact, things go the other way. Figure 1 gives a scatter plot of countries’ tariff rates (applied, simple
mean, all products [%]) against the natural log of GDP (PPP, constant 2011 international dollars), both on
five 5‐year averages from 1991 to 2015 (N = 749, Source: World Development Indicators). The red re-
gression line indicates a significant negative relationship between log GDP and the mean tariff: a pooled
OLS gives the slope of –0.680 (robust standard error: 0.126), implying that an increase in log GDP by one
unit (i.e., an increase in GDP by 2.718 times) tends to decrease the mean tariff by 0.680%. Furthermore,
breaking down log GDP into log GDP per capita and log population, the former has a more negative and
significant slope of –2.896 (robust standard error: 0.205), whereas the latter loses its significance (slope:
0.00124; robust standard error: 0.166). These results are robust even if GDP in constant 2010 U.S. dollars
is used instead of GDP in PPP.3 This means that an economically larger country (in terms of GDP per
capita rather than population) tends to set a lower tariff in contrast to the existing optimal tariff theory.
Broda, Limão, and Weinstein (2008) try to resolve this puzzle from an empirical perspective by
using data on highly disaggregated (i.e., four‐digit Harmonized System) product categories for 15
countries that set their tariffs freely before joining the WTO from the 1990s to the early 2000s. They
find that the actual tariffs follow the optimal tariff formula, that is, tariffs are higher for products
whose estimated inverse export supply elasticities are large. However, they do not report direct evi-
dence that countries with larger GDP tend to set higher tariffs as the existing theory suggests. How can
we explain the fact that a larger country sets a lower tariff?4 The purpose of this paper is to develop a
new optimal tariff theory that is consistent with the data.
We depart from the DFS Ricardian optimal tariff model of Opp (2010) in one respect: eco-
nomic growth. Empirical research around 2010 (e.g., Estevadeordal & Taylor, 2013; Wacziarg &
Welch, 2008) shows that trade liberalization does indeed raise economic growth, thereby overcoming
Rodriguez and Rodrik’s (2000) concern for robustness. If this is true, then a welfare‐maximizing
country may be less willing to set a high tariff. To address this point, we incorporate import tariffs into
the framework developed by Naito (2012), who combines the multi‐country AK endogenous growth
model of Acemoglu and Ventura (2002) with the DFS Ricardian model to study the dynamic effects of
changes in iceberg trade costs. By doing this, we can derive a country’s dynamic optimal tariff, which
is directly comparable with its static version corresponding to Opp (2010).
FIGURE 1 Log of GDP PPP and tariff rate
Source. World Development Indicators [Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT