Is the wage equation spatial enough? Evidence from a novel regional trade dataset

Date01 August 2018
AuthorAurélien Fichet de Clairfontaine,Christoph Hammer
Published date01 August 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12315
SPECIAL ISSUE PAPER
Is the wage equation spatial enough? Evidence from
a novel regional trade dataset
Aur
elien Fichet de Clairfontaine
|
Christoph Hammer
Vienna University of Economics and
Business (WU), Vienna, Austria
Correspondence
Christoph Hammer, Department of
Economics, Vienna University of
Economics and Business (WU),
Welthandelsplatz 1, 1020 Vienna,
Austria.
Email: chhammer@wu.ac.at
Abstract
This study focuses on the market accessibility of European
regions and its relationship to income per capita, summar-
ized in the new economic geography (NEG) wage
equation. In a first step, we make use of a novel dataset of
bilateral trade flows for 254 European nomenclature of terri-
torial units for statistics (NUTS-2) regions (for 26 European
countries excluding Bulgaria and Romania) in order to esti-
mate trade costs and ultimately construct a regional measure
of access to markets. In a second step, we test the hypothesis
that access to domestic as well as to foreign markets
increases income per capita. We find that, in spite of its spa-
tial formulation, the wage equation is not able to capture
local spatial patterns of the distribution of European regional
income per capita.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Ever since the seminal work of Krugman (1991), models of new economic geography(NEG) have
attempted to shed light on the uneven economic distribution using a general equilibrium framework
with a focus on geography represented by transport or trade costs. They aim to explain agglomeration
patterns by allowing mobile production factors to move across space to regions with the highest
rewards. While historical and institutional factors as well as the physical geography of a region can
help explain agglomeration, NEG models focus on forces that reflect the behavior of optimizing
(mobile) economic agents.
One central element of NEG models that is derived from optimizing agents is the so-called wage
equation.It states that the maximum wage that each firm in a specific region can afford to pay is a
function of trade-cost-weighted market and supply capacities(Redding & Venables, 2004, p. 58).
This means that NEG models imply a spatial structure in which remunerations of factors are higher in
regions that have better access to markets or a higher real market potential.
This relation was first introduced by Harris (1954), who used geographical distance to weigh
income from all other regions. Real market potential has some advantages over the basic concept of
Harris. It is derived from microeconomic theory and considers competition among firms in export
610
|
V
C2017 JohnWiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev IntEcon. 2018;2 6:610633.
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12315
markets. Additionally, it is constructed with trade costs that are more broadly defined than as a function
of distance only.
The empirical literature can be divided into three main approaches that to some extent also differ in
their research questions.
1
The first strand was pioneered by Redding and Venables (2004). They use a
two-step approach to estimate the wage equation. First, in order to construct a measure for market
access they estimate a gravity-type trade equation to obtain estimates of trade costs. Trade costs repre-
sent every form of friction in shipping goods, services, people or ideas over space. In the most general
case one can think of the sum of transport costs, information and time costs, institutional and cultural
barriers (such as tariffs, product standards, and language).
2
In a second step, the wage equation is esti-
mated with the constructed measure for market access. They find robust evidence for the role that mar-
ket access plays for explaining income differences between 101 countries.
A second line of research usually uses more disaggregated data to estimate the wage equation.
Hanson (2005) studies the wage equation derived from Helpmans extension of Krugmans core
periphery model, for U.S. counties between 1970 and 1990. In contrast to the above-mentioned two-
step approach, he estimates the wage equation in a single step using nonlinear least squares. The
advantage of this approach is the possibility to identify most theoretical parameters. Among the draw-
backs are the sensitivity of nonlinear least squares to starting values and demanding data requirements
to simultaneously model all the equilibrium conditions.
3
The third approach builds on the second and is a combination of estimation and simulation. It tries
to bring the estimated coefficients back into the theoretical model. Brakman, Garretsen, and Schramm
(2006) and Bosker, Brakman, Garretsen, and Schramm (2010) argue that, in order to interpret the
results of a NEG wage equation, one should study the implications for economic agglomeration within
the NEG model from which the equation was motivated. For them, the wage-equation estimates are a
prior for model simulations.
We follow the two-step approach put forward by Redding and Venables (2004) but in contrast to
earlier studies, our analysis is based on a novel cross-regional trade dataset for 254 European NUTS-2
regions for 2010. To the best of our knowledge there is no study that follows the two-step approach
with such detailed data for the overall European Union. One advantage of this is the ability to stay
close to the theoretical model and to use Krugmans real market potential.
4
Since the internal economic
structure of countries is usually biased towards large urban areas, regional heterogeneity would be lost
in a national analysis. Compared with other studies with a regional focus that also use two steps (see,
e.g., Head & Mayer, 2004; Breinlich, 2006), we are able to estimate trade costs for each of 254
2
region
pairs with a fully specified gravity equation. Earlier papers either had to work with national data and
impose homogeneous trade costs within a country or modeled trade costs as a function of distance
only.
An additional new element is the way in which we considerspatial correlation when we estimate the
regional wageequation in the second step. Comparedwith earlier formulations (seeFingleton & Fischer,
2010; Fingleton, 2010; or Bruna, Lopez-Rodriguez,& Faí~
na, 2016) we argue that a NEG wage equation
with real market potential should not be represented by a spatial autoregressive model. Instead we use
spatial filtering techniques (Tiefelsdorf and Griffith, 2007) in orderto control for spatial dependence.
Our results are consistent with earlier findings on the ability of real market potential, and more
especially its foreign component, to explain regional distribution of income per capita among European
regions. While the effect of domestic market potential, that is, a regions home market, is negligible,
we show that foreign market potential is a strong determinant of income per capita even when correct-
ing for regional spatial dependences. Furthermore, an analysis of remaining spatial autocorrelation sup-
ports recent findings in the literature, at the time of writing, that the wage equation cannot capture local
patterns but rather accounts for a global spatial trend.
FICHET DE CLAIRFONTAINE AND HAMMER
|
611

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT