Interprovincial Migration and Human Capital Formation in China*

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12089
Date01 June 2016
AuthorYukari Suzuki,Yui Suzuki
Published date01 June 2016
Interprovincial Migration and Human Capital
Formation in China*
Yui Suzuki and Yukari Suzuki
Received 4 April 2013; accepted 12 April 2015
Weexamine how the rising interprovincial migration of individuals with diverse ed-
ucational backgrounds affected human capital formation in China in the 1990s. We
nd that gross outow migration of those with higher and lowerlevels of education,
respectively, has human capital incentive and disincentive effects. Our estimates
suggest that the incentive effect eclipses the disincentive effect in general; however,
a surge of migration, particularly among less educated groups, implies more of a
disincentive effect in China in the 1990s. We also nd that changes in the relative
labor supply resulting from net outow migration mitigate a direct brain drain by
both encouraging and discouraging school enrolments.
Keywords: brain drain, China, human capital, migration, schooling.
JEL classication codes: J24, J61, O15.
doi: 10.1111/asej.12089
I. Introduction
There has been concern that the emigration of high-skilled workers from develop-
ing countries to developed countries would have adverse effects on the developing
countries and widen NorthSouth inequality (Beine et al., 2001). Rich countries
hence become richer at the expense of poor countries who suffer as a result of a
reduction in human capital, or a brain drain. Since the 1970s, institutional set-
tings such as domestic labor market rigidity and scal and technological external-
ities have been studied to explore the negative welfare consequences of the brain
drain in developing countries (e.g. Bhagwati and Hamada, 1974; McCulloch and
Yellen, 1977). Later in the 1990s, further studies employing endogenous growth
frameworks reached more or less the same conclusion with regards to the negative
effect of the migration of highly skilled workers from developing countries (e.g.
Miyagiwa, 1991; Haque and Kim, 1995). These arguments start with a self-
*Yui Suzuki (corresponding author): Facultyof Economics, Finance Department, Musashi Univer-
sity, 1-26-1 Toyotama-kami Nerima-ku, Tokyo 176-8534 Japan. Email: yui-szk@cc.musashi.ac.jp.
Yukari Suzuki: Department of Economics, University of Michigan, 611 Tappan St. Ann Arbor, MI
48109-1220 United States. Email: yukaris@umich.edu. The authors are grateful to Charles Brown, Al-
bert Park, Jan Svejnar and anonymous referees for their guidance and helpful comments. Wealso thank
the Institute of Population and Labor Economics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences for providing
us with the aggregated migration ow data tabulated based on the census data.
© 2016 East Asian Economic Association and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
Asian Economic Journal 2016, Vol.30 No. 2, 171195 171
bs_bs_banner
evident truth: migration inevitably alters the geographical allocation of human
capital. In this context, destination economies are the winner, gaining human cap-
ital embodied in migrants, and source economies are the loser, when, as is often
the case, people drained from the economy are highly educated.
However,since the late 1990s, a series of papers have challenged the pessimistic
brain drain argument, by suggesting that the emigration of high-skilled workers
from developing countries can be benecial for the source countries. This claim
is supported by an important point neglected in the brain drain argument: a
countrys pre-migration human capital stock is endogenous to the prospect and re-
alization of migration. Some studies assert that there may be benecial impacts of
international migration on source countries: that there is a brain gain, through un-
certainty in migration (Mountford, 1997; Stark et al., 1998; Beine et al., 2001,
2008), migrantsremittances (Edwards and Ureta, 2003; Hanson and Woodruff,
2003; Borraz, 2005; Yang, 2008), return migration (Borjas and Bratsberg, 1996;
Stark et al., 1997) and migrantsnetworks (Kanbur and Rapoport, 2005). These
ndings suggest that source countries can alleviate the direct loss due to brain drain
by increasing human capital investment through a variety of channels.
1
These new insights into international migration highlight the possibility that do-
mestic migration inuences the total amount of human capital available at the na-
tional level as well as impacting the distribution of human capital across regions. If
migration does not affect the incentive for new human capital formation, migration
within a national territory, unlike the international case, would merely alter the re-
gional distribution of human capital in a country. However, this is not true when we
take into account the brain gain: internal migration alters new human capital in-
vestment and, thus, can change the overallhuman capital stock at the national level.
Because there are more changes of residence through domestic migration, domes-
tic migration can have a greater inuence on new human capital formation.
The present study examines how the internal migration of individuals with di-
verse educational backgrounds affects human capital formation in source econo-
mies and explores the implications for the development of regional and national
economies. According to Beine et al. (2001) the prospects of migration foster in-
vestments in education when international migrants are positively selected based
on education and skills; we apply this conjecture to domestic migration. A better
chance of migration for the educated, who seek higher returns to their human cap-
ital in the destination, provides the younger generation with greater incentive to
enroll into schools in the source economy. Following Docquier and Rapoport
(2004), we refer to this benecial effect as the human capital incentive effect.
However, we must be mindful of one point for our purpose: domestic migration
differs from international migration, discussed in Beine et al. (2001), in that those
with higher skill levels and education do not necessarily comprise the majority of
migrants. A higher prospect of migration for the less educated can have an
1 Docquier and Rapoport (2004, 2012) review literature on the brain drain and brain gain through
international migration, including recent empirical works.
ASIAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL 172
© 2016 East Asian Economic Association and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT