International intellectual property rights protection and economic growth with costly transfer

AuthorKazuyoshi Ohki
Date01 November 2017
Published date01 November 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12298
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
International intellectual property rights protection
and economic growth with costly transfer
Kazuyoshi Ohki
Kanazawa University, Japan
Correspondence
Kazuyoshi Ohki, Faculty of Economics
and Management, Institute of Human
and Social Sciences, Kanazawa
University, Kakuma, Kanazawa 920-
1192, Japan.
Email: kazuyoshi.ohki@gmail.com
Abstract
This paper develops a product-cycle model with costly tech-
nology transfer, which requires resources from both the
North and the South. In the basic model, we show that
strengthening intellectual property rights (IPR) protection
induces a large technology transfer and narrows the North
South wage gap. However, we obtain an ambiguous result
regarding the effect on economic growth, which depends
crucially on the size of the transfer cost. Although strength-
ening IPR protection induces a high growth rate when the
transfer cost is small, it can induce a low growth rate when
the transfer cost is large. In the extended model, in order to
examine what factors determine the transfer cost, we con-
sider the situation where the Southern firms may misbehave
and the Northern firms incur a cost to monitor them. We
show that the degree of investor protection and the degree of
morality in developing countries influence the size of the
transfer cost, which affects economic growth.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Since the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreement, which requires
developing countries that are members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) to establish minimum
standards of intellectual property rights (IPR) protection, when a range of measures were signed in the
Uruguay Round, many studies have analyzed the effects of strengthening IPR protection in developing
countries. These studies typically construct a model consistent with the product cycle, as highlighted in
Vernon (1966). New goods are invented and production takes place initially in high-wage developed
countries. Subsequently, production shifts to low-wage developing countries, accompanied by technol-
ogy transfer. Technology diffuses from developed countries to developing countries through many
channels. Regardless of the channels, technology transfer involves substantial resource cost in both
countries. For example, when technology transfer takes place through foreign direct investment (FDI),
affiliates receiving technology will typically need to conduct R&D to absorb the technology and to
modify it for the local market, and multinational firms will need to train workers in developing
1130
|
V
C2017 JohnWiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev IntEcon. 2017;25:11301154.
Received: 12 June 2016
|
Revised: 15 February 2017
|
Accepted: 26 April 2017
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12298
countries and to acquire knowledge about foreign customs and regulations.
1
When technology transfer
takes place through licensing, there is a negotiation cost incurred to establish an agreement. However,
many theoretical papers ignore the cost of technology transfer. In particular, no study has considered
that technology transfer involves a resource cost in both developed countries and developing countries.
This paper, therefore, develops a product-cycle model with costly technology transfer, which requires
resource use in both developed and developing countries.
2
We assume that there are two countries in the world, the North and the South. New goods are
invented in the North, and inventors of the new good can earn a profit flow because they are protected
by perfect IPR protection in the North. They have an incentive to transfer technology to the South in
order to produce goods using Southern labor, whose wage is relatively low. They suffer, however, from
a one-off imitation risk and transfer cost. These trade-offs determine the amount of technology transfer
in the equilibrium. Then we analyze the effect of strengthening IPR protection. Strengthening IPR pro-
tection (decreasing imitation risk) induces a large technology transfer and narrows the NorthSouth
wage gap. Strengthening IPR protection reduces imitation risk, which decreases the disadvantage of
transferring technology. Then, more inventors are willing to transfer technology and more production
shifts to the South, which induces increased demand for Southern labor. This reduces the NorthSouth
wage gap. These results are consistent with models in related studies in which technology diffuses
through FDI or licensing. However, we obtain ambiguous results regarding the effect on economic
growth. Although strengthening IPR protection induces a high growth rate when the transfer cost is
small, strengthening IPR protection can induce a low growth rate when the transfer cost is large.
Strengthening IPR protection induces a production shift to the South, which is accompanied by a tech-
nology transfer. On the one hand, more production takes place in the South, which makes Northern
resources shift from production to R&D activities, which promotes economic growth. On the other
hand, more technology transfer takes place, which requires Northern resources. The resources used in
R&D will shift to the transfer activities, which impedes economic growth. If the former (latter) effect
dominates the latter (former) effect, strengthening IPR protection promotes (harms) economic growth.
Then the question is What factors determine the transfer cost?,which plays a key role in our
model. In the real world, it depends not only on the characteristics of the firms in the developed coun-
try such as the ability to conduct adaptive R&D and to accumulate knowledge, but also on the charac-
teristics of the host countries such as education level and the degree of maturity in the financial market.
With respect to the characteristics of the host countries, there are large gaps in terms of human capital
and the degree of maturity of legal systems, even within the developing countries. In our extended
model, we focus our attention on the role of monitoring activity to show that the characteristics of the
host countries affect transfer cost and consequently economic growth. Specifically, we introduce a
moral hazard framework.
We assume that for firms in developed countries to shift production to developing countries it is
necessary to cooperate with entrepreneurs in the developing countries, and that entrepreneurs have an
incentive to enjoy private benefits by misbehaving. These private benefits depend on the degree of
investor protection, the morals of workers in developing countries, and the monitoring by the firms
transferring the technology. When the degree of investor protection and the morals of laborers are low,
private benefits are high. Firms can reduce the private benefits of entrepreneurs by monitoring, which
involves a resource cost. Although the characteristics of host countries are not so important when the
degree of investor protection and the morals of laborers are sufficiently high, they have a crucial effect
on the transfer cost when the degree of investor protection and the morals of laborers are low because
firms must monitor entrepreneurs to ensure that they do not misbehave. The transfer cost is high if the
degree of investor protection and the morals of laborers in the host country are low. In this situation,
strengthening IPR protection impedes economic growth. This result implies that strengthening IPR
OHKI
|
1131

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT