International credit markets and global business cycles

AuthorYi Wen,Xiaochuan Xing,Patrick A. Pintus
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12206
Date01 March 2019
Published date01 March 2019
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12206
International credit markets and global business cycles
Patrick A. Pintus,Yi Wenand Xiaochuan Xing
This paper stresses a new channel through which global financial linkages contribute to the
co-movement in economic activity across countries. We show in a two-country setting with
borrowing constraints that international credit markets are subject to self-fulfilling variations in
the world real interestrate. Those expectation-driven changes in the borrowing cost in turn act as
global shocks that induce strong cross-country co-movementsin both financial and real variables
(suchas asset pr ices,g rossdomestic product, consumption, investment, and employment). When
firms around the world benefit from unexpectedly low debt repayments,the y borrowand invest
more, which leads toexcessive supply of collateral and of loanable funds at a low interest rate, thus
fueling a boom both at home and abroad. As a consequence, business cycles are synchronized
internationally. Such a stylized model thus offers one way to rationalize both the existence of
a world business-cycle component, documented by recent empirical studies through dynamic
factor analysis, and the factor’s intimate link tog lobal financial markets.
Key wor ds world interest rate, international co-movement, self-fulfilling equilibria
JEL classification E21, E22, E32, E44, E63
Accepted 11 October 2018
1 Introduction
Empirical evidence suggests that there exists a set of common factors behind business cycles across
nations. This set of global factors has affected national outputs of many countries simultaneously
over the last 50 years. For example, Kose, Otrok, and Whiteman (2003) document the existence of
a distinct world business cycle in a 60-country sample that spans seven regions of the world over
the period 1960–90. More specifically, they show that on top of country-specific shocks, a world
factor is also important and accounts for a significant fraction of country-specific business-cycle
variations. In particular, this global factor accounts for about 35% of the variances of output and
of consumption in the USA, which turns out to be more than the regional or the country-specific
factors can explain.
Kose, Prasad, and Terrones (2003) report similar results and further show that financial linkages
between countries are more important for international business-cycle transmissions in economies
CNRS-InSHS and Aix-Marseille University, CNRS-InSHS D´
el´
egation Paris Michel-Ange, Paris, France. Email:
patrick.pintus@univ.amu.fr
Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis, St Louis, Missouri, USA and TsinghuaUniversity, Beijing, China.
YaleUniversity, New Haven,Connecticut, USA.
This article has been written in honor of Roger Farmer,whose intellectual cur iosity,academic achievements and generous
friendship have both enriched and inspired us. Wethank very much Jess Benhabib, Kazuo Nishimura, and Makoto Yano
for inviting us to contribute to this special issue, as well as a referee for comments and suggestions and St´
ephane Auray
for discussions. The usual disclaimer applies.
International Journal of Economic Theory 15 (2019) 53–75 © IAET 53
International Journal of Economic Theory
International credit markets Patrick A. Pintus et al.
that are more open to international capital flows (see also Imbs 2004). More recently, Crucini et al.
(2011) also confirm that the world-wide business cycle is as important as the nation-specific business
cycles and they also find that “real interest rates are dominated by a common G-7 component,w ith
two-thirds of the variance attributable to the common factor and almost none attributed to the
nation-specific component” (p. 167). In other words, in G7 countries real interest rates exhibit
variations that appear to be driven by a common global factor.Therefore, not only do national levels
of output and consumption follow a world component, but so also do financial variables.
In sum, the existing body of empirical evidence strongly points to the existence of a few world
common factors that explain international co-movements of both output and financial variables. In
addition, financial linkages between countries through international capital and debt markets are
suspected to play a key role in explaining these common factors. Of striking importance is the fact
that a common component drives much of the co-movementin different countries’ interest rates, at
least in developed economies.
However,little is known theoretically about the nature of such common factors behind world real
output and financial variables, uncovered through dynamic factor analysis in the studies reviewed
above. One obvious candidate is global technology shocks. But the hypothesized existence of global
technology shocks suffers from the lack of micro-level empirical evidence that innovations at the
firm level are synchronized globally despite different institutional arrangements, such as patent laws
and government efforts to protect technological secrets. It is not obvious that different countries’
technology frontiers progress and regress at the same time.
International trade is another possible source of global business cycle propagation (see, for
example, Miyamoto and Nguyen 2017). But it takes time for goods and services to move across
borders: shipping time often takes weeks if not months from one country to another. So the role of
shocks to the speed of global shipping or trade costs in generating the world business cycle is also
likely to be limited.
This paper proposes that the existence of a global financial market sets the conditionfor the r ise of
financial and real global factors that cause global business cycles. Weshow how the existenceof a g lobal
financial market makes it possible for investors’expectations to be coordinated around the world. In
particular, global sentiments originating from the world financial market can simultaneously drive
both global interest rates and national outputs across the world. Intuitively, financial markets are
connected much more tightly and in a more timely manner across nations than goods and labor
markets, yet within each country the goods and labor sectors are closely connected to the financial
sector. Asa result, animal spirits in the world financial market can simultaneously affect the financial
and real variables in each country (especially across developed economies, which are morefinancially
globalized).
Thus, we develop a very simple setting with two countries that are open to international financial
capital flows, within which cross-national credit borrowing and lending operate under collateral
constraints to alleviate defaults. We deliberately assume that production factors such as labor, land,
and capital are not mobile across national borders to highlight the role of global financial linkages
in generating global real business cycles.
More specifically,we assume that in each country households are international lenders and firms
are international borrowers, through a global bond market, under the standard assumption that the
former are more patient than the latter (`alaKiyotaki and Moore 1997). Although borrowing and
lending are channeled through a world financial market, production factors in each country cannot
be traded across countries. In other words, in each country firms (households) can borrow (lend)
internationally (subject to a collateral constraint) and the world interestr ateon financial debt adjusts
to reflect the tightness of the global supply and demand for loans.
54 International Journal of Economic Theory 15 (2019) 53–75 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT