Informal one‐sided target zone model and the Swiss franc

Published date01 November 2018
AuthorRichhild Moessner,Yu‐Fu Chen,Michael Funke
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12352
Date01 November 2018
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Informal one-sided target zone model and the Swiss
franc
Yu-Fu Chen
1
|
Michael Funke
2
|
Richhild Moessner
3
1
Business and Management Studies,
University of Dundee, United Kingdom
2
Department of Economics, Hamburg
University and CESifo Munich, Germany
3
Bank for International Settlements,
Basel, Switzerland
Correspondence
Richhild Moessner, Bank for
International Settlements,
Centralbahnplatz 2, 4002 Basel,
Switzerland.
Email: richhild.moessner@bis.org
Abstract
This paper develops a new theoretical model with an asym-
metric informal one-sided exchange rate target zone, with an
application to the Swiss franc following the removal of the
minimum exchange rate of CHF 1.20 per euro in January
2015. We extend and generalize a standard target zone
model by introducing perceived uncertainty about the lower
edge of the band. We find that informal soft edge target
zone bands lead to weaker honeymoon effects, wider target
zone ranges, and higher exchange rate volatility than formal
target zone bands. These results suggest that it would be
beneficial for exchange rate policy intentions to be stated
clearly in order to anchor exchange rate expectations and
reduce exchange rate volatility. We also study how
exchange rate dynamics can be characterized in models in
which financial markets are aware of occasional changes in
the policy regime. We show that expected changes in the
central banks exchange rate policy may lead to exchange
rate oscillations, providing an additional source of exchange
rate volatility, and to capture this it is important to take into
account the possibility of regime changes in exchange rate
policy.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Since the outbreak of the euro area crisis, Swiss exchange rate policy has been a hotly debated topic.
From September 2011 to January 2015 the official exchange rate policy of the Swiss National Bank
(SNB) was to maintain a minimum exchange rate of CHF 1.20 per euro. To achieve this objective, the
central bank stated that it would be willing to buy foreign currency in unlimited quantities. On 15 Janu-
ary 2015, the SNB took markets by surprise with its decision to discontinue Switzerlands currency
floor (Jerman, 2016; SNB, 2015).
Countering an appreciating currency ought to be easier than countering a depreciating currency.
A central bank trying to prop up the exchange rate can run out of foreign exchange (FX) reserves.
Received: 30 October 2017
|
Accepted: 18 April 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12352
1130
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2018;26:1130–1153.
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
A central bank aiming for depreciation can credibly promise to buy as much foreign currency as it
takes, since it can print its own currency in unlimited amounts. By discontinuing the so-called mini-
mum exchange rateinJanuary 2015, the SNB showed that a theoretically unlimited strategy to defend
a currency floor may have practical bounds. In particular, there may be an upper limit tohow far a cen-
tral bank balance sheet can grow, including owing to concerns about potential future losses on FX
reserves, as suggested for example by Amador, Bianchi, Bocola, and Perri (2016). Amador et al.
(2016) provide a theoretical model in which a central bank wants to maintain an exchange rate peg,
and responds to increases in demand for domestic currency by expanding its balance sheet. They
model so-called reverse speculative attackstriggered by the concern of future balance sheet losses of
the central bank. They find that the interaction between the desire to maintain an exchange rate peg
and the concern about future balance sheet losses can lead the central bank to first accumulate a large
amount of reserves, and then to abandon the peg, and conclude that this was just as had been observed
in the Swiss case. The fact that a Swiss referendum was held on 30 November 2014 over the proposi-
tion that the SNB should hold at least 20 percent of its reserves in gold (The Economist, 2014), sug-
gests that there was some political pressure to limit losses on the central banks balance sheet, even
though the referendum was defeated. Thus there may be a limit to conducting central bank policy by
steering the exchange rate. As a consequence, the SNB resorted, like many other central banks, to cut-
ting interest rates with all the risks of feeding market distortions that such a policy may entail (see
Bank for International Settlements, 2010).
The model presented in this paper applies to the situation where there is no formal one-sided target
zone for the currency, but where there are market perceptions of an informal one-sided target zone.
This may have been the case following the discontinuation of the SNBs currency floor in January
2015, since proxy measu res for the SNBs foreign exchange interventions presented below suggest
that the SNB likely continued to intervene in the FX market.
In light of the fact that exchange rate regimes have been at the centre of academic debate and have
been a major concern for policymakers in recent years, this paper develops a new theoretical model
with an asymmetric informal (unofficial, not publicly announced) one-sided target zone. Such a model
incorporates the notion that the target zone can be seen as a partially credible commitment device. It
can be regarded as a generalization of Krugmans (1991) simple target zone model of exchange rates.
In the standard model, the peg and the hard edge boundaries are publicly announced and credible, and
market arbitrage mechanisms and interventions take place in whatever amounts are necessary to pre-
vent the target zone from being violated. Our paper is not a normative analysis of the best exchange
rate policy or exchange rate target, especially given uncertainty about fundamental drivers of exchange
rates.
We find that informal soft edge target zone bands lead to weaker honeymoon effects, wider target
zone ranges, and higher exchange rate volatility than formal target zone bands. The honeymoon effect
stabilizes the exchange rate relative to its fundamentals. It refers to the phenomenon that, if the Swiss
franc is close to the informal floor, the probability increases that the Swiss franc will hit the floor, which
leads to perceived interventions by the central bank. These results suggest that it would be beneficial for
exchange rate policy intentions to be stated clearly in order to anchor exchange rate expectations and
reduce exchange rate volatility. We also study how exchange rate dynamics can be characterized in
models in which financial markets are aware of occasional changes in the policy regime. We show that
expected changes in the central banks exchange rate policy may in addition be a source of exchange
rate oscillations, providing an additional source of exchange rate volatility, and to capture this it is
important to take into account the possibility of regime changes in exchange rate policy.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the evolution of the Swiss franceuro exchange
rate, and Section 3 presents proxy measures for the SNBs foreign exchange interventions as a function
CHEN ET AL.
|
1131

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT