Importing exporters and exporting importers: A study of the decision of Chinese firms to engage in international trade

Date01 February 2019
AuthorLiyun Zhang,Nicholas J. Horsewood,Robert J.R. Elliott
Published date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12374
240
|
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:240–266.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In a world where globalization is under threat from a renewed interest in protectionist policies it is
important to understand what drives the exporting and importing behavior of firms and whether these
activities are complementary or are substitutes. The existing literature has tended to concentrate on
exporting and shows that exporters tend to outperform non exporters in terms of productivity, capi-
tal intensity, skilled labor intensity, size and financial health (Bernard & Jensen; 2004; Greenaway,
Guariglia & Kneller, 2007; Lawless, 2009; Van Biesebroeck, 2005). Central to this literature is the
identification of factors that determine a firm’s decision to export, with a number of studies identify-
ing sunk‐entry costs and various firm characteristics as important determinants of exporting behavior
(Das, Roberts & Tybout, 2007; Greenaway & Kneller, 2008; Impullitti, Irarrazabal & Opromolla,
2013; Manez, Rochina‐Barrachina & Sanchis, 2008).1
Received: 25 March 2016
|
Revised: 21 June 2018
|
Accepted: 26 June 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12374
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Importing exporters and exporting importers: A
study of the decision of Chinese firms to engage in
international trade
Robert J. R. Elliott
|
Nicholas J. Horsewood
|
Liyun Zhang
Department of Economics,University of
Birmingham, Birmingham, UK
Correspondence
Robert J. R. Elliott, Department of
Economics, University of Birmingham,
Birmingham, UK.
Email:r.j.elliott@bham.ac.uk
Funding information
ESRC, Grant/Award Number:
RES‐000‐22‐3959
Abstract
This paper examines the complex and interdependent rela-
tionship between importing and exporting for a panel of
Chinese manufacturing firms. We estimate the decision to
import and export simultaneously within a dynamic ran-
dom‐effects bivariate probit framework addressing the en-
dogenous initial conditions problem. Results show that
decisions to export and import are simultaneously deter-
mined and that sunk-entry costs play a significant role in a
firm’s decision to enter international markets. Costs are
larger for exporting. We also find a substitution effect be-
tween the two decisions. The substitutability between ex-
porting and importing is greater for financially constrained
private firms.
|
241
ELLIOTT et al.
In contrast, relatively little attention has been given to explain the decision of firms to import.
More general papers on importer behavior include MacGarvie (2006), Kugler and Verhoogen (2009),
Chen and Ma (2012), Augier, Cadot and Dovis (2013), Cadot, Carrere and Strauss‐Kahn (2014), and
Halpern, Koren and Szeidl (2015). The results of these and other papers show that importers tend to
share many of the same characteristics as exporters in that they are larger (importers are generally
larger than exporters), more productive and more capital‐ and skill‐intensive than non traders. In
addition, there are a small number of papers that study importing and exporting simultaneously (a sig-
nificant number of exporters also import intermediate inputs) that show that these so‐called two‐way
traders are even larger, more productive and more capital‐ and skill‐intensive than firms that only ex-
port or only import (Aristei, Castellani, & Franco, 2013; Bernard, Jensen, & Schott, 2009; Castellani,
Serti, & Tomasi, 2010; Kasahara & Lapham, 2013; Manova & Zhang, 2009; Muuls & Pisu, 2009).2
Central to this paper is the observation that access to intermediate inputs from abroad increases
both the probability of exporting and the number of export destination countries (Bas, 2012; Bas &
Strauss‐Kahn, 2014; Fugazza & McLaren, 2014)). The argument is that a firm will face lower sunk‐
entry costs to exporting if it is already an importer especially if the imports are sourced from the target
export destination country. In this case, the firm is likely to be, for example, more familiar with that
country’s language and culture and may be able to exploit existing distribution channels and previ-
ously developed networks. Similarly, existing exporters should also find it easier to begin an importing
relationship because of similar trade externalities/complementaries that lower the sunk‐entry costs of
importing. The potentially complex and interdependent relationship between importing and exporting
means that estimations that fail to take into account the influence of existing trade channels on the
decision to participate in further international trade may bias (overstate) the size of sunk costs of entry
for that particular channel.
Following Melitz (2003) and Bernard and Jensen (2004), a number of theoretical models and
empirical studies have suggested that decisions to export and import are state dependent and that
persistence in exporting and importing may be due to the large costs to individual firms of entering
foreign markets (Aeberhardta, Buonob & Fadinger, 2014; Campa, 2004; Kaiser & Kongsted, 2008;
Kasahara & Lapham, 2013; Timoshenko, 2015). These costs can be categorized into upfront sunk
costs (e.g., finding reliable buyers/suppliers and establishing distribution channels) and fixed costs
(e.g., contracting costs, transportation costs, and customer service costs). Sunk costs are assumed to be
incurred before a firm enters a foreign market and hence cannot be recovered whether the firm remains
or subsequently exits the market.3
In this paper we revisit the literature on the internationalization decision of firms employing a
large dataset of manufacturing firms for China between 2002 and 2006 that contains rich information
on a range of different firm characteristics and international trade activities. China is also central to
current global trade patterns when it overtook the United States as the world’s largest trader (WTO).4
China has attracted particular interest given its rapid growth of international trade. A number of recent
papers examine the export behavior of Chinese firms (Lu, 2010; Yang & Mallick, 2010; Yi & Wang,
2012). Although there are also a number of papers that consider the performance of Chinese importers
(Elliott, Jabbour & Zhang, 2016; Manova & Zhang, 2009; Wang & Yu, 2012) there is only limited
research that has been done on the importing decision of firms. Although Fan, Li and Yeaple (2015)
and Feng, Li and Swenson (2016) link the two sides of international trade in studies of manufacturing
firms in China, their focus is on how imported inputs affect export performance.
More specifically, we make the following contribution. First, rather than focusing on only one side
of a firm’s internationalization strategy (exporting or importing), we estimate the probability of a firm
engaging in both importing and exporting jointly, controlling for the effects of any previous trading
relationship (exporting or importing). In doing so we are examining whether importing and exporting

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT