Implications of negative interest rate policies: An early assessment

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12249
Date01 February 2018
Published date01 February 2018
AuthorTemel Taskin,Carlos Arteta,M. Ayhan Kose,Marc Stocker
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Implications of negative interest rate policies:
An early assessment
Carlos Arteta
1
| M. Ayhan Kose
1,2
| Marc Stocker
1
| Temel Taskin
1
1
Development Prospects Group, World Bank,
Washington, DC
2
Brookings Institution, CEPR; CAMA,
Washington, DC
Correspondence
M. Ayhan Kose, Development Prospects Group,
The World Bank Group, 1818 H Street NW,
Washington, DC 20433.
Email: akose@worldbank.org
Abstract
Over the past few years, several central banks have imple-
mented negative interest rate policies (NIRP) to provide
additional monetary policy stimulus. This paper presents an
early assessment of the domestic and global implications of
NIRP by analysing the behaviour of a set of key financial
variables. We report three main results. First, since the intro-
duction of NIRP, many of the key financial variables have
evolved broadly, as implied by the standard transmission
channels. For the euro area, the responses of these financial
variables following NIRP announcements are directionally
consistent with those of conventional interest rate cuts. Sec-
ond, NIRP could pose risks to financial stability but there is
no conclusive evidence as yet of a significant impact on
bank profitability or of a broad-based increase in leverage.
Third, the responses of assets of emerging market and
developing economies to NIRP announcements are on aver-
age broadly consistent with those to other types of expan-
sionary monetary policy measures.
1|INTRODUCTION
1
A number of central banks, including the Danmarks Nationalbank (DNB), the European Central
Bank (ECB), the Swiss National Bank (SNB), Swedish Riksbank, the Bank of Japan (BoJ) and the
Central Bank of Hungary (MNB), have employed negative interest rate policies (NIRP) to provide
additional monetary policy stimulus over the past few years (Figure 1). These central banks are now
charging (instead of paying) commercial banks for their excess reserves (Table 1). Countries with
NIRP account for approximately one quarter of world GDP as of August 2016. In conjunction with
the implementation of NIRP, yields on a sizable class of sovereign bonds in some of these countries
have also declined significantly.
1
This paper draws from Arteta, Kose, Stocker, and Taskin (2016) who provide a comprehensive analysis of the issues discussed.
Received: 1 December 2016 Accepted: 1 April 2017
DOI: 10.1111/1468-0106.12249
8© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/paer Pac Econ Rev. 2018;23:826.
The use of NIRP aimed to show central banksresolve to meet their policy objectives, as the
perceived zero lower bound constrained their ability to commit to additional policy easing. In partic-
ular, the main motivation for the implementation of NIRP by the ECB, the BoJ, Riksbank and the
MNB was the need to stabilize inflation expectations and support growth. In the case of the SNB
and the DNB, an immediate motivation was the need to respond to currency appreciation and capital
inflow pressures. For central banks implementing quantitative easing (QE) policies, two additional
considerations were the narrowing pool of assets eligible for their purchase programmes and the
possibility of diminishing returns from QE.
Historically, negative interest rates (policy-determined or otherwise) have been an extremely
rare phenomenon. In the United States, some Treas ury bill yields briefly fell below zero during
the Great Depression and during the height of the 20082009 global financial crisis. The SNB
sporadically introduced negative interest rates on foreign deposits during the 1970s to prevent
capital inflows and excessive appreciation of the Swiss franc (Meggyesi, 2010). Yields on
some Japanese government bonds were negative for a brief period during the downturn of the
late 1990s. Swedish Riksbank temporarily lowered its deposit rate below zero in 2009. How-
ever, the widespread emergence of negative interest rates outside of a financial crisis is
unprecedented.
A cut in policy rates slightly below zero should, in principle, have similar effects as a cut in rates
to low but positive territory. However, policy rates substantially below zero for a protracted period
of time could lead to greater risks of financial market disruptions. NIRP, like other unconventional
monetary policy measures, could also have spillover effects on emerging market and developing
economies (EMDE), as search for yields in reaction to negative rates in advanced economies may
affect capital flows to EMDE.
The unprecedented use of NIRP in multiple countries has not just extended the boundaries of
unconventional monetary policies but also fuelled an already polarized debate on the implications of
these policies. Some argue that NIRP have so far served the intended purpose, complementing the
broader set of expansionary measures employed by central banks (Bernanke, 2016; Draghi, 2016).
Others, however, emphasize financial stability risks associated with NIRP and claim that they may
have weakened bankswillingness to lend, contributed to financial market distortions, further
inflated asset prices, and delayed the implementation of necessary macroeconomic and structural
policies (Carney, 2016; White, 2014).
Despite these highly polarized discussions, research on the implications of NIRP has been lim-
ited. The present paper examines the short-term domestic and global implications of NIRP by
employing a set of event studies. The event study methodology has been commonly used in the
–1
0
1
2
Jan-14 Jul-14 Jan-15 Jul-15 Jan-16 Jul-16 Jan-17
Euro area Sweden Japan
Switzerland Denmark Hungary
tnecrePtnecreP
FIGURE 1 Policy interest rates. Sources: European
Central Bank, Bank of Japan, Swedish Riksbank, Swiss
National Bank, Danmarks Nationalbank, Central Bank of
Hungary, Haver Analytics, Bloomberg and World Bank.
Notes: Policy rates are the following: euro area, overnight
deposit facility; Sweden, repo rate; Japan, current account
deposit; Switzerland, middle point of target range for 3-
month LIBOR; Denmark, 1-week certificate of deposit;
Hungary, overnight deposit. Last observation is
February 2017
ARTETA ET AL.9

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT