Good deal indices in asset pricing: actuarial and financial implications

AuthorJosé Garrido,Ramin Okhrati,Alejandro Balbás
Published date01 July 2019
Date01 July 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/itor.12424
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 1475–1503
DOI: 10.1111/itor.12424
INTERNATIONAL
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
RESEARCH
Good deal indices in asset pricing: actuarial and financial
implications
Alejandro Balb´
asa,Jos
´
e Garridoband Ramin Okhratic
aUniversity Carlos III of Madrid, C/Madrid, 126, 28903 Getafe, Madrid, Spain
bDepartment of Mathematics and Statistics, Concordia University,1455 de Maisonneuve Blvd. W., Montreal, Canada
H3G 1M8
cMathematical Sciences, University of Southampton, Highfield, Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK
E-mail: alejandro.balbas@uc3m.es [Balb´
as]; jose.garrido@concordia.ca[Garrido]; r.okhrati@soton.ac.uk [Okhrati]
Received 23 September 2016; receivedin revised form 28 January 2017; accepted 14 April 2017
Abstract
Weintegrate into a single optimization problem a risk measure, beyondthe variance, and either arbitrage-free
real market quotations or financial pricing rules generated by an arbitrage-free stochastic pricing model. A
sequence of investment strategies such that the couple (expected return, risk)divergesto(+∞,−∞)will be
called a good deal (GD). The existence of such a sequence is equivalent to the existence of an alternative
sequence of strategies such that the couple (risk, price)divergesto(−∞,−∞). Moreover, by appropriately
adding the riskless asset, every GD may generatea new one only composed of strategies priced at one. We will
see that GDs often exist in practice, and the main objective of this paper will be to measure the GD size. The
provided GD indices will equal an optimal ratio between both risk and price, and there will exist alternative
interpretations of these indices. They also provide the minimum relative (per dollar) price modification that
prevents the existence of GDs. Moreover, they will be a crucial instrument to detect those securities or
marketed claims that are over- or underpriced. Many classical actuarial and financial optimization problems
may generate wrong solutions if the used market quotations or stochastic pricing models do not prevent the
existence of GDs. This fact is illustrated in the paper, and we point out how the provided GD indices may be
useful to overcome this caveat. Numerical experiments are also included.
Keywords: risk measure; compatibility between prices and risks; good deal size measurement; actuarial and financial
implications
1. Introduction
The use of risk functions beyond the variance is becoming more and morefrequent in both actuarial
and financial studies. Nevertheless, when the most important arbitrage-free pricing models of
financial economics (binomial, trinomial trees, Black and Scholes,stochastic volatility, etc.) and the
most important risk functions (VaR,CVaR,weight ed -CVaR,robust -CVaR, spectral measures, etc.)
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA02148,
USA.
1476 A. Balb´
as et al. / Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 1475–1503
are combined in a single problem, one often faces the existence of sequences of investment strategies
(good deals or GDs) whose pairs (expected return, risk)divergeto(+∞,−∞). The existence of GDs
is equivalent to the existence of alternativesequences of investment strategies whosepairs (risk, price)
diverge to (−∞,−∞). This pathological finding has been analyzed in Balb´
as and Balb´
as (2009)
and Balb´
as et al. (2016a), where explicit examples of the sequences above have been constructed
and their performance empirically tested. The main conclusion was that the divergence of (expected
return, risk)to(+∞,−∞)is more theoretical than real, but the performance of the constructed
GD was good enough. The GD were collections of options providing much better realized Sharpe
ratios than their underlying assets.
In this paper, we will deal with a couple (ρ, ) composed of the risk measure ρand the pricing
rule . The pair (ρ, ) will be called noncompatible if it implies the existence of a GD,andthe
main objective of this paper will be the measurement of the GD size by means of a new index
denoted by ˜
Nor ˜
N(ρ, ). An important precedent in financial theory is the notion of arbitrage.
Although the absence of arbitrage always holds in theoretical approaches, real market quotations
sometimes reflect the existence of arbitrage. For this reason, some years ago many authors defined
several measures of the arbitrage size. This allowed them to address interesting questions such as
pricing and hedging issues under transaction costs, cross-market arbitrage, integration between
markets, trading systems, valuation of embedded derivatives, etc. Similarly, the existence of GD (or
the lack of compatibility) must be measured now, because in some sense it indicates an important
lack of balance between the risk that the investor is facing and the wealth that he/she is expecting.
As we will see, these unbalanced situations may lead to wrong decisions in several fields. For
instance, managers could pay too high prices or compose inefficient portfolios, and insurers could
buy nonoptimal reinsurance contracts or receive insufficient premiums.
The arbitrage measurement has been addressedfrom several perspectives. One of them wasrelated
to the capital profits generated by an arbitrage strategy (Balb´
as et al., 1999). Nevertheless, if the
arbitrage strategy can be repeated time and again, the arbitrage profit will be multiplied time and
again also, and therefore it will become infinity. To prevent this caveat, Balb´
as et al. (1999) measure
the arbitrage level as the maximum ratio between the arbitrage income and the value of the sold
assets, that is, these authors give a relative measure of the arbitrage degree. Similarly, when (risk,
price)divergesto(−∞,−∞)we will need to maximize the risk/pr ice ratios, otherwise we will face
unbounded optimization problems.
Arisk/price ratio is an objective function that does not satisfy manydesirable analytical properties
(continuity, convexity, differentiability, etc.), therefore its optimization can be simplified by dealing
instead with vector optimization problems involving both risk and price. Since Harry Markowitz
published his seminal results, it is known that multiobjective analyses are useful in many financial
topics. In particular, for portfolio selection several interesting approaches exist, such as Ballestero
and Romero (1996), Ballestero et al. (2012), Dash and Kajiji (2014), among others. With respect
to the simultaneous optimization of both risk and price, we apply well-known results to optimize
“risk” under constraints for “price” (Sawaragi et al., 1985).
The paper outline is as follows. Section 2 sets notations and lists assumptions. The index (or
measure) ˜
N(ρ, ) is derived in Section 3. The first approach will apply when no theoretical pricing
model is considered, and only a finite collection of available securities and their market quotations
are involved. The advantage of this approach is clear, since it is sufficient to choose a robust (or
ambiguous) risk function ρfor the value of ˜
Nto be model-independent. Beyond the optimal
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT