Globalization and urban polarization

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12366
Date01 November 2018
Published date01 November 2018
AuthorAnthony J. Venables
Rev Int Econ. 2018;26:981–996. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
981
1 | INTRODUCTION
The benefits of globalization for consumers are spread widely across income groups and regions in
a country, but the production impact is concentrated on particular sectors and firms. This sectoral
concentration maps into differential impacts on towns and cities, as well as on skill types. Adjustment
to such spatially concentrated shocks seems, from the experience of many countries, to be particu-
larly difficult. Cities in the rustbelt of the United States or former manufacturing areas in the north
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12366
SPECIAL ISSUE PAPER
Globalization and urban polarization
Anthony J. Venables1,2,3
Paper written for the conference in celebration of Jim Markusen on the occasion of his retirement, September 2017, Boulder
CO. Thanks to participants in the seminar and discussant Bob Staiger for helpful comments.
1Department of Economics, University of
Oxford, Oxford, UK
2Centre for Economic Policy Research,
London, UK
3International Growth Centre, London, UK
Correspondence
A. J. Venables, Department of Economics,
University of Oxford, Manor Road, Oxford
OX1 3UQ, UK.
Email: tony.venables@economics.ox.ac.uk
JEL Classification
F12, R11, R12
Abstract
External trade affects the internal spatial structure of an
economy, promoting growth in some cities or regions and
decline in others. Internal adjustment to these changes has
often proved to be extremely slow and painful. This paper
combines elements of urban and international economics
to draw out the implications of trade shocks for city per-
formance. Localization economies in production of inter-
nationally tradable goods mean that cities divide into two
types, those producing tradables and those specializing in
sectors producing just for the national market (nontrada-
bles). Negative trade shocks (and possibly also some posi-
tive ones) reduce the number of cities engaged in tradable
production, increasing the number producing just nontra-
dables. This has a negative effect across all nontradable
cities, which lose population and land value. Remaining
tradable cities boom, gaining population and land value.
Depending on the initial position, city size dispersion may
increase, thus raising the share of urban land rents in na-
tional income and reducing the share of labor.
982
|
VENABLES
of the United Kingdom and northern France have spent decades in relative, and sometimes absolute,
decline. The more recent experience of the China trade shock has been mapped into regional impacts,
in particular by the work of Autor et al. (for a survey see Autor, Dorn, & Hanson, 2016). In this work,
adjustment failure is viewed as a consequence of labor market rigidities, typically a combination of in-
adequate labor mobility, insufficient wage flexibility, or both, leading to an outcome with persistently
low levels of employment in affected areas.1
This paper explores a different mechanism through which trade or technology shocks create per-
sistent regional and urban inequalities. We assume a perfectly functioning labor market—with factor
mobility and wage flexibility—and focus on the difficulties faced in establishing new tradable sectors
in cities that have lost a traditional tradable goods sector. The difficulties arise as many of these sectors
are subject to agglomeration economies that create a first‐mover problem; in the absence of coordinated
behavior, it is not profitable to start a new activity in a new place. This problem is compounded by the
fact that, within a country, factor mobility limits the magnitude of spatial wage variation meaning that
costs do not fall enough to attract activity into a place that has experienced a negative shock. In short, the
usual mechanisms of comparative advantage do not operate to draw activity into an adversely affected
area.
We show circumstances under which trade shocks—positive as well as negative—lead to a polar-
ization of the urban structure as some cities boom and others decline. Declining cities maintain eco-
nomic activity, but it is in sectors producing nontradable goods and services. As an increasing number
of cities are relegated to specializing in these sectors the relative price of nontradables declines, am-
plifying the gap between cities. The counterpart of cities that have lost tradable sectors is booming
cities that have retained tradable goods or service sectors. These expand, driving up land prices in
these cities and possibly also the share of rent in income (actual and imputed to land and property
owners). These booming cities are as much a feature of trade shocks as are declining cities that have
lost competiveness in tradable goods production.2
The paper presents a simple model of this process, combining elements of urban economics and
international trade. At the heart of the model are three features. The first is the presence of agglomer-
ation economies, that is, external economies of scale, operating at the city or region level and within
a particular productive sector (localization economies). It is this that gives rise to spatial clustering of
sectors, meaning that different cities within a country will undertake different economic activities and
that trade shocks will impact different areas in different ways. The model assumes that all tradable
sectors are subject to these economies, although non‐tradable sectors are not. A further consequence of
agglomeration economies is that it is difficult to establish new centers of production for tradable goods.
A city that has lost a traditional sector offers neither low enough factor prices nor any productivity ad-
vantage in a new sector. Coordinated action by firms—or a “large developer”—can solve the problem,
but without this no firm wants to be the first in the sector to establish in a new location, uncertain as to
whether it will be followed by other firms which will create the cluster and raise productivity.
The second feature is that we distinguish between tradable and nontradable sectors, where by non-
tradables we mean goods produced for the national rather than the international economy, and hence
have their price set domestically rather than fixed at world prices.3 A central feature of the model is
that cities in a country will divide between those producing tradables and those producing nontrad-
ables. Trade shocks may cause cities to switch activity with, for example, cities that lose their tradable
sector due to import competition defaulting to non‐tradable production.
The third feature is that, within a country, the performance of a city depends largely on its absolute
advantage, not its comparative advantage. If a country’s export sector has a negative shock the ad-
justment mechanism is a real depreciation, that is, a reduction in its wage and unit costs relative to its
trading partners, and this reduction continues until other sectors become competitive. If a city within

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT