Gains from Trade Under Monopolistic Competition

AuthorRobert C. Feenstra
Date01 February 2016
Published date01 February 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12150
GAINS FROM TRADE UNDER MONOPOLISTIC
COMPETITION
ROBERT C. FEENSTRA*University of California, Davis and National Bureau of
Economic Research
Abstract. The monopolistic competition model in international trade predicts three sources of gains
from trade that are not present in traditional models: consumer gains from having access to new
import varieties of differentiated products; gains from a reduction in rm markups due to import com-
petition; and gains from the self-selection of more efcient rms into export markets, provided that
rms are heterogeneous in their productivities. With the added assumption that the distribution of
rmsproductivity is Pareto, and with a support thatis unbounded above, we argue that only the third
source of gains from trade, due to the self-selection of rms, operates. This result helps to explain the
simple formula for the gains from trade found by Arkolakis et al. (2012). If the Pareto distribution is
bounded above, however, then all three sources of gains from trade operate once again.
1. INTRODUCTION
The monopolistic competition model in international trade predicts three sources
of gains from trade that are not present in traditional models. First, there are the
consumer gains from having access to new import varieties of differentiated
products. That source of gains from grade has been demonstrated for the United
States by Broda and Weinstein (2006), for example, using the formula for the ex-
actconstant elasticity of substitution (CES) price index from Feenstra (1994).
These gains depend on one minus the share of expenditure on new imports, raised
to a negative power that depends on the elasticity of substitution in consumption.
Second, the monopolistic competition model also allows for gains from a
reduction in rm markups due to import competition. This second source of
gains was stressed in Krugman (1979), but has been absent from much of the
later literature due to the assumption of CES preferences, leading to constant
markups. Research in Feenstra and Weinstein (2010), using the translog expen-
diture function allows those gains to be measured for the United States. They
nd that the welfare gains from reduced markups for the United States are of
roughly the same order of magnitude as the gains from product variety.
The extensionof the monopolistic competition model to allowfor heterogeneous
rms, due to Melitz (2003) and discussed in Section2, leads to a third source of
gains from the self-selection of more efcient rms into export markets. With the
added assumption that the distribution of rmsproductivity is Pareto, as in
Chaney (2008),then that source of gains hasbeen shown to have a very simplefor-
mula by Arkolakis et al. (2012): the gains from trade depend on one minus the
share of expenditure on imports (equal to the share of expenditure on domestic
*Address for Correspondence: Robert C. Feenstra, University of California, Davis, and National
Bureau of Economic Research. E-mail: rcfeenstra@ucdavis.edu. The material in this article will ap-
pear in Chapter 6 of Robert C. Feenstra, Advanced International Trade, 2nd edition, to be released in
2015 by the Princeton University Press.
Pacic Economic Review, 21: 1 (2016) pp. 3544
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12150
© 2016 Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
bs_bs_banner

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT