From Equality of Deprivation to Disparity of Prosperity: The Poverty–Growth–Inequality Triangle in Post‐reform China

AuthorYan Zhang,Guanghua Wan,Chen Wang,Hua Yin
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/cwe.12236
Date01 March 2018
Published date01 March 2018
©2018 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
China & World Economy / 50–67, Vol. 26, No. 2, 2018
50
*Guanghua Wan, Professor, School of Economics, Chongqing Technology and Business University, China.
Email: guanghuawan@yahoo.com; Chen Wang, Assistant Professor, School of Urban and Regional Science,
Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China. Email: wang.chen@mail.shufe.edu.cn; Hua Yin,
Assistant Professor, School of Shanghai Development, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China.
Email: yin.hua@mail.shufe.edu.cn; Yan Zhang (corresponding author), Specially-Appointed Professor, School
of Economics, Chongqing Technology and Business University, China. Email: phd09010@grips.ac.jp. The
authors gratefully acknowledge nancial support from the Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 7 1703088)
and Shanghai Pujiang Program (No. 17PJC045).
From Equality of Deprivation to Disparity of Prosperity:
The Poverty–Growth–Inequality Triangle in
Post-reform China
Guanghua Wan, Chen Wang, Hua Yin, Yan Zhang*
Abstract
In the post-reform era, China achieved poverty reduction that was unprecedented in
human history This poverty reduction was accompanied by fast growth and worsening
income distribution. The present paper examines the poverty–growth–inequality triangle
in China by: (i) providing growth, inequality and poverty proles at the national and
provincial levels; (ii) uncovering the contributions of growth and inequality changes
to poverty reduction; and, nally, (iii) drawing lessons for other developing countries.
Based on the World Bank’s denition of the poverty line, China has already eliminated
abject poverty, even though the poverty rate was as high as 88.3 percent in 1981. The
remarkable record in poverty reduction is predominantly attributable to growth. The
effect of inequality varied in different periods. In addition, the impact of growth on
poverty reduction is found to be diminishing over time, a phenomenon worth further
research and policy attention.
Key words: China, income distribution, poverty-growth-inequality triangle
JEL codes: O1, P25, R1
I. Introduction
In 1978, China was one of the poorest countries in the world, with an average GDP per
capita of RMB423.2, or approximately US$184.0 based on the ofcial exchange rate.
Based on the World Bank’s denition of the poverty line of US$1.90 (2011 purchasing
©2018 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
The Poverty–Growth–Inequality Triangle in Post-reform China 51
power parity-adjusted), 88.3 percent of Chinese citizens were in poverty in 1981. The
rate for those in rural areas of China was as high as 95.6 percent.1 However, China
was an egalitarian society. According to our own estimates, the Gini index for China
remained below 0.35 from 1978 to 1988. Thus, it can be said that pre-reform China was
a country with equality of deprivation.
Reform began in late 1978, starting with the rural sector, where the majority
of citizens (87.5 percent) lived (NBS, 1981). The so-called “household agricultural
production responsibility system” replaced the commune system, and incentives
were provided to work hard and work smart. Agricultural output and incomes rose
signicantly, stimulating demand for non-farming products and laying the foundation for
industrialization. Wasting no time, reform attention was shifted to the industrial sector
in 1984 when both the urban sector and the town and village enterprises began miracle
expansions. These expansions generated demand for manpower, which was met by the
huge amount of surplus labor that existed in rural China, and aided by the improvement in
farming productivity and living standards since the late 1970s. The virtuous cycle began.
It is important to point out that in the same year of 1984 when reform was extended
to the non-farming sectors, many special economic zones were set up in the coastal
areas, signalizing the opening up of China to international trade and foreign direct
investment (FDI). The opening-up strategy received a signicant boost in early 1992,
when China’s reform architect Deng Xiaoping undertook the well-known Tour of
Southern China. Then in 2001, China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO).
China’s opening up and subsequent integration into the global economy enabled China
to exploit its comparative advantage in labor endowment and to grow without demand
constraint. As a result, China’s GDP expanded at an average rate of more than 9 percent
per annum for more than 30 years until 2011 (NBS, various years). Even after the
nancial crisis, China maintained a moderate growth rate, averaging 7.3 percent from
2012 to 2016 (NBS, various years).
The fast growth led to a dramatic improvement in the living standard of ordinary
citizens, lifting hundreds of millions of Chinese people out of poverty. According to the
World Bank, China’s poverty rate based on the US$1.90 per day poverty line decreased
from 88.3 percent in 1981 to 1.85 percent in 2013. Even based on the moderate poverty
line of US$3.10 per day, poverty reduced dramatically, from a rate of 99.1 percent in
1981 to 11.1 percent in 2013.2 In fact, the most important target of the Millennium
Development Goals of the United Nations (i.e. halving global poverty between 2000 and
2015) would not have been achieved if China were excluded.
1,2See PovcalNet of the World Bank.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT