Foreign Language Learning and Trade

AuthorVictor Ginsburgh,Jacques Melitz,Farid Toubal
Published date01 May 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12268
Date01 May 2017
Foreign Language Learning and Trade
Victor Ginsburgh, Jacques Melitz, and Farid Toubal*
Abstract
The paper is devoted to an econometric analysis of learning foreign languages in allparts of the world. Our
sample covers 193 countries and 13 important languages. Four factors significantly explain learning: world
population of speakers of home language, trade with speakers of foreign language, linguistic distance
between home and foreign language and literacy. Trade may well deserve more emphasis than the other
three factors, not only for its significance, but also because its direction can change faster and by a larger
order of magnitude. Controlling for any of the 13 target languages, including English, is of no particular
importance.
1. Introduction
There is wide awareness of the role of foreign trade in stimulating learning of foreign
languages.
1
Yet despite much research to date on the influence of common languages
on foreign trade,
2
the influence of trade on language learning has been studied very lit-
tle.
3
In general, econometric work on language learning has been largely confined to
the decision of immigrants and linguistic minorities to learn the primary language in
their country of residence in order to increase their work possibilities and wages.
4
In this paper, we concentrate instead on learning foreign languages, meaning lan-
guages in common use abroad but not at home. Quite explicitly, we do not treat the
learning of the home language by immigrants and by linguistic minorities, possibly
concentrated in certain regions, like Basque speakers in Spain or Gujarati speakers in
India. This learning is largely a different subject, we think. Most nationals acquire their
language as children, almost without effort, while for residents who do not know the
home language, learning it is likely to dominate learning of any foreign language since
the person may well need the home one for daily living.
We also take a world perspective on learning foreign languages. Thus, we study learn-
ing of 13 languages in 193 countries. These languages are Chinese, English, Spanish, Ara-
bic, Russian, French, Portuguese, German, Malay, Japanese, Turkish, Italian and Dutch,
in descending order of number of speakers. The languages are chosen because of their
importance in either of two senses or both: sheer size or international spread. One of our
basic concerns was increasing the sample variance. Specifically, we wanted to include
* Ginsburgh: European Center for Advanced Research in Economics and Statistics (ECARES),
Universit
e libre de Bruxelles, 50 Av. F. D. Roosevelt, CP 114/04, 1050 Bruxelles, Belgium. Tel: 132-2-
650-3846; Fax: 132-2-650-4012; Also affiliated to CORE, Universit
e catholique de Louvain, Belgium. E-
mail: vginsbur@ulb.ac.be. Melitz: Ecole Nationale de la Statistique et de l’Administration Economique
(ENSAE), 3 Avenue Pierre Larousse, 92240 Malakoff, France. Also affiated to Centre d’
Etudes
Prospectives et d’informations Internationales (CEPII), Paris, France and Centre for Economic Policy
Research (CEPR), London, UK. Toubal: Ecole Normale Sup
erieure de Cachan, Cachan 94230, France.
Also affiliated to Paris School of Economics and CEPII, Paris France. The authors would like to thank
the participants in seminars at CREST, Paris, Ekaterinburg, Russia, University of Jaume 1, Castelon,
Spain, and ECARES, Belgium, for valuable comments. They are especially indebted to Julien Martin
and Olivier Loisel for their comments. Farid Toubal wishes to acknowledge the support provided by the
iCODE Institute (Idex Paris-Saclay).
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Review of International Economics, 25(2), 320–361, 2017
DOI:10.1111/roie.12268
some languages that are large but not widely spread. Chinese and Japanese fit the bill,
especially the latter. We also wanted to have some languages with only a moderate popu-
lation of speakers in any one country but notable international spread. Malay and Dutch
are our best examples. Our data is cross-sectional and centers around 2005. We examine
five separate influences on learning based on elementary theoretical considerations and
the availability of data, and all five of them emerge as important with the expected sign.
Four of these influences entered in earlier theoretical discussion of language learning in a
game-theoretical context (see Selten and Pool, 1991; Church and King, 1993; Shy, 2001).
The first of these four influences is the size of the world population of speakers of a for-
eign language; it encourages learning. The second is literacy (as a reflection of the ability
to learn), which encourages learning too. Third, a large world population of speakers of
the home language discourages learning. People who possess a large language have less
incentive to learn any other one. Fourth, linguistic distances also discourage learning.
When the distance between languages increases, learning decreases. The fifth influence, at
the heart of this study, is trade. Trade with speakers of a foreign language raises learning
of the speakers’ language. Of major note, trade is well correlated with geographical prox-
imity to speakers, common borders with them, past historical ties to them, and current
economic and political associations with them. Therefore its influence could reflect many
factors besides commerce. This is part of the interest of the variable. Separating out these
various sources of the variable’s influence would be a fitting subject for later research.
There are obvious differences between the operations of the five influences. Literacy
encourages learning without regard to the target language. The size of the home lan-
guage discourages learning generally too. By contrast, the size of the population of the
target language, and trade with this particular population, both promote learning of
the particular language. Finally, the linguistic distance between home and target lan-
guage affects the choice of foreign language to learn.
The various motives for language learning that are reflected in trade emerge as the
most important factor in our empirical findings. Conditional on the presence of learners
of a language in a country, a 1 percentage-point increase in the trade share with speak-
ers of the language will increase learners of the language (as a percentage of the total
population) by around 1.4 percentage points. This is a large effect. It emerges after con-
trolling for the reciprocal effect of learning on the trade share; that is, after instrument-
ing the trade share. Without conditioning on positive learning, a 1% increase in the
trade share with speakers will also increase the probability of some positive learning
after controlling for endogeneity. A doubling of the trade share causes a 13% probabil-
ity of some positive learning. This next effect is smaller than the aforementioned one
but as precisely estimated. These are also estimates without separate individual controls
for national specificities. If we control for such specificities by introducing a separate
fixed effect per country, the influence of trade on learning even goes up. It rises from
1.4 to 2.1 percentage points for learning when there is some and from a 13% to a 16%
probability of learning overall.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides some theoretical discussion of the
influences on learning that we choose to investigate in the empirical study. Section 3
discusses the econometric model. Section 4 turns to the data and section 5 describes
the estimation method. Sections 6–8 are devoted to results.
2. The Theoretical Background
In explaining language learning on a world basis, the game-theoretical literature pro-
vides a useful point of reference. This literature would suggest treating the total
FOREIGN LANGUAGE LEARNING AND TRADE 321
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
numbers of speakers of the different languages in the world and the costs of learning
as outstanding factors. To explain, assume that there is a single home language per
country and that everyone in each country possesses this language. In each country,
therefore, all people can already communicate with the whole world population of
speakers of their home language, including those who live abroad. The larger this total
world population is, the better able they are to communicate and the lower are their
marginal benefits of learning another language. Therefore, the total world population
of speakers of the home language exerts a negative influence on learning at home.
This theoretical result accords well with common experience. We encounter more
monolingualism in large-language countries, such as the USA or the UK, than in
small-language ones, such as the Baltic countries.
In the case of each country, consider next the total world number of speakers of a
foreign language. The larger this number is, the larger are the benefits of learning the
language. On this ground, Chinese and English should attract more learning than
other languages since they are the two largest in the world. Arabic and Spanish should
rank high too.
However, as the game-theoretical literature stresses (see Gabszewicz et al., 2011;
Selten and Pool, 1991), there are costs of learning, if only the time and effort required
to learn. One international measure of this cost is the distance between the home and
the foreign language. The specific measure of this distance we shall use rests on expert
judgments by ethnolinguists. This should clearly help to reconcile the evidence with
the fact, for example, that there is less learning of Chinese, Japanese and probably
Arabic in countries using Indo-European languages than sheer numbers of speakers
would lead us to expect. Another indicator of the cost of learning is the literacy rate.
Higher literacy, implying higher education, should make learning easier and thereby
promote learning of foreign languages.
If we limit ourselves to the preceding influences on learning, however—namely,
world numbers of respective speakers of home and target language, linguistic distance
and literacy—we miss one important dimension, if not several. Consider the relative
interest of learning English, French and German in a Spanish-speaking country in
South America as opposed to Spain. For both countries, world speakers of these lan-
guages and the linguistic distances between them are exactly identical
5
and differences
in the literacy rate cannot explain a preference for learning one language rather than
another. Yet it is evident that French and German are of greater interest relative to
English in Spain than South America because of higher levels of interaction with
French- and German-speaking countries in Spain. Introducing bilateral trade ties
between countries is one important means of repairing this difficulty. It is not the only
one. We tried others that proved of less interest, as we will see. Also, two of the other
possible influences—geographical distance to speakers and common border with
speakers—could not be combined with trade, though they mattered, since they serve
as instruments for trade. They are thus only reflected through trade. As already
emphasized, bilateral trade ties reflects many things, not only commercial ties but also
geography, politics and possibly history, for example, a common ex-colonial past. In
addition, the impact of this variable is multi-faceted. From the standpoint of people as
consumers, trade ties are an additional reflection of the benefits of learning foreign
languages besides the world number of speakers. Indeed, in the presence of trade ties,
the total world population of speakers of a target language is possibly best interpreted
as reflecting non-market advantages of learning this language, stemming from the abil-
ity to interact socially with foreign speakers and to benefit from their cultures and cul-
tural heritages (though trade ties will cover these advantages to a non-negligible
322 Victor Ginsburgh, Jacques Melitz, and Farid Toubal
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT