Foreign Direct Investment with Endogenous Technology Choice

AuthorBenteng Zou,Herbert Dawid
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12202
Published date01 February 2017
Date01 February 2017
FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT WITH ENDOGENOUS
TECHNOLOGY CHOICE
HERBERT DAWID Bielefeld University
BENTENG ZOU*University of Luxembourg
Abstract. In this paper, we analyse the optimal foreign direct investment (FDI) of a rm operating in
a duopolistic market. FDI induces technological spillovers to a competitor in theforeign country; the
intensity of which depends on the absorptive capacity of the foreign rm and the size of the techno-
logical gap. We characterize a technology spillover threshold and show that for an intensity of spill-
overs below this threshold, there is a unique locally asymptotic stable steady state with a positive
capital stock in the developing country. Furthermore, we characterize how optimal foreign invest-
ment patterns and the investors value function depend on the level of technology transferred and
characterize the optimal level to be used for the FDI.
1. INTRODUCTION
Based on UNCTAD statistics, worldwide foreign direct investment (FDI) in-
creased by a factor of more than 10 from 1983 to 2003.1This trend continued
from 2003 to 2013, with the FDI inward and outward ows doubling again.
While most FDI is still undertaken in industrialized countries, such as the
USA, the UK, France, Italy and the Netherlands, investment ows are increas-
ing to the newly industrializing countries (NIC), especially Asia (mainly China
and India) and Central and Eastern Europe, which have recently joined the
EU. Indeed, the UNCTAD statistic presents that the emerging market takes
more and more shares in the worldwide FDI, from less than 1/5 in 1983 to
almost half in 2013 at the aggregate of inward and outward of FDI.
The motivation for rms to invest in NIC is primarily to gain access to these
markets and to benet from, in part, drastically lower factor costs there, where
cost considerations are often the main factor inuencing the location decisions
of rms. For example, Ireland provides a considerable tax incentive for foreign
rms by offering a corporate tax rate of 10% to all manufacturing rms produc-
ing in Ireland (see Görg and Greenaway, 2004). Governments reasons for their
desire to attract FDI seem clear. Investment raises employment and growth, and
may also generate positive spillover effects for local rms. The latter seems to be
of particular importance for NIC, which hope to gain access to modern technol-
ogies in this way. Empirical studies using rm-level data tend to conrm that
FDI triggers positive spillovers. Examples in this respect are analyses of
*Address for Correspondence: Benteng Zou, CREA, University of Luxembourg, 162a avenue de la
Faiencerie, L1511, Luxembourg. E-mail: benteng.zou@uni.lu. Financial support under COST
Action IS1104: The EU in the new economic complex geography: models, tools and policy evaluation
is gratefully acknowledged. We appreciate the useful discussions with Luisito Bertinelli, Raouf
Boucekkine, and Ioana Salagean.
1The UNCTAD Foreign direct investment database is available online: http://unctadstat.unctad.
org/wds/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=88.
Pacic Economic Review, 22: 1 (2017) pp. 322
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12202
© 2017 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
bs_bs_banner
FDI-induced spillovers in Venezuela (Aitken and Harrison, 1999), Lithuania
(Javorcik, 2004), Hungary (Halpern and Murakozy, 2007) and Romania
(Smarzynska and Spatareanu, 2008), and of Chinese manufacturing rms
(Liu, 2008b), as well as the study of Gorodnichenko et al. (2014) covering 17
emerging market economies.2
Such positive spillovers increase over time the productivity and competitive-
ness of the rms located in the NIC and, if these rms are competing in the same
markets with high-technology investors, these investors have to be concerned
about the danger of reducing or even losing their competitive edge in the long
run. Hence, a trade-off between short-run cost reductions and spillover-induced
long-run productivity gains of competitors arises when rms decide on their for-
eign investment pattern. In light of this trade-off, the factors determining the size
of the emerging spillovers play an important role in the determination of rms
foreign investment policy. In the empirical and theoretical literature on spill-
overs and catch-up dynamics, different such factors have been highlighted. First,
starting with the seminal contribution of Nelson and Phelps (1966), a number of
studies have stressed that the gap to the frontier inuences the speed of catch-up
in the laggard region in terms of human capital (e.g. Benhabit and Spiegel, 1994)
or technology (e.g. Wang and Blomstrom, 1992; Boucekkine et al., 2006). Sec-
ond, the absorptive capacity of the laggard region, which positively depends
on the technological level of the local rms, has been identied as an important
factor inuencing the size of the spillovers. Whereas the concept has originally
been introduced with focus on the individual rmslevel (Cohen and Levinthal,
1989), both theoretical and empirical
work
has extended the scope of the concept
to whole regions (see e.g. Aghion and Javarel (2015) for a recent survey). Third,
the size of the investment, and associated with that the size of the employment
and the locally produced output of the foreign investor, has an increasing effect
on the generated spillovers (e.g. Das 1987; Wang and Blomstrom, 1992; Petit
et al., 2000; Dawid et al., 2010).
The purpose of this paper is to analyse optimal foreign investment behaviour
in a dynamic setting incorporating all these three factors that inuence the spill-
over size. More precisely, we consider a high-technology rm, which may reduce
production costs through moving parts of the production to an NIC. However,
such foreign investment generates spillovers to a local rm in the host country
that competes with the investor in a common oligopolistic market. Hence, the
high-tech rm faces the dynamic trade-off described above and given the
discounted long-term prot stream it is not obvious that foreign investment is
protable for the rm. Identifying conditions on key parameters, like the initial
technology gap or the basic spillover intensity, which induce positive foreign in-
vestment, as well as examining the implications of the choice of the level of tech-
nology to be used in the NIC are the main objectives of this paper. The dynamic
approach adopted in this study distinguishes our analysis from most of the
2It should be mentioned that for some countries empirical studies fail to nd evidence of systematic
positive productivity spillovers. An example in this respect is Hale and Long (2011) considering
Chinese data.
Z. BENTENG4
© 2017 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT