Foreign direct investment subsidy in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with heterogeneous firms

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12430
AuthorMing‐Jen Chang,Shikuan Chen,Yen‐Chen Wu
Date01 November 2019
Published date01 November 2019
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:1427–1459. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie
|
1427
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The reduction in barriers to international investment and the globalization trend of the world economy
over the past two decades (1996‐2016) have led to substantial increases in foreign direct investment
(FDI). The growth in FDI has induced a phenomenon (see, for example, Figure 1’s global FDI in-
flows) whereby the competition to attract capital inflow from multinational corporations (MNCs) is
rather pervasive. Many countries keen on attracting FDI claim that it not only promotes economic
performance for them as the host country, but also brings other benefits, including the possibility of
advanced technology transfers, the infusion of much‐needed capital, a substitution for imports, and
job creation. Since FDI subsidies typically induce a direct consumption gain for the host country,
because those new MNCs utilizing the subsidy scheme relocate their production facilities and then set
Received: 17 December 2018
|
Revised: 4 June 2019
|
Accepted: 1 July 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12430
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Foreign direct investment subsidy in a dynamic
stochastic general equilibrium model with
heterogeneous firms
Yen‐ChenWu1
|
ShikuanChen1,2
|
Ming‐JenChang3
1Department of International
Business,National Taiwan University,
Taiwan
2Chung‐Hua Institution for Economic
Research, Taiwan
3Department of Economics,National Dong
Hwa University, Taiwan
Correspondence
Yen‐Chen Wu, Department of International
Business, National Taiwan University,
No.1, Sec. 4, Roosevelt Rd., Taipei City
10617, Taiwan.
Email: yenchen1978@gmail.com
Abstract
This study analyzes the macroeconomic impacts of subsi-
dies to attract multinational corporations when firms are de-
termining whether to enter or how to serve foreign markets.
We show that a small FDI subsidy scheme induces con-
sumption gains and delivers short‐term welfare improve-
ment for the FDI host country if firms differ in productivity.
However, the subsidy generates a new problem and results
in the wealth reallocation effect, leading to welfare deterio-
ration for the host country in the long run. Moreover, we
find that a subsidy program induces a welfare improvement
for the host country if it is offered to all domestic producers
instead of foreign producers only in the host country.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F12; F13; F23; L23
1428
|
WU et al.
lower prices in the host country as a result of savings on cross‐border transport costs, the usage of FDI
subsidies has become increasingly common (Figure 2).1
However, the direct costs of funding such as
a policy intervention result in a negative effect on the host country’s consumption. Thus, there is no
guarantee that the aggregate consumption in the host country increases when the government adopts
an FDI subsidy program to entice more MNCs.
The earlier literature is theoretically ambiguous as to whether the FDI subsidy policy induces a net
welfare improvement for the host country.2
Chor (2009) shows that a small subsidy delivers a welfare
gain for the host country when firms differ in productivity levels. However, he fails to consider that
such a small subsidy would also cause a substantial reduction in the number firms in the host country
as well as the aggregate income of the host country’s households in the long run. In order to cope
with the decrease in wealth, the host country’s households will gradually reduce their consumption.
Accordingly, the net effects of FDI subsidies on the host country’s welfare are still ambiguous when
taking into account the subsequent change in the number of firms in both countries.
This study builds a two‐country dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with het-
erogeneous firms and endogenous entry as developed by Ghironi and Melitz (2005). It allows firms to
serve foreign markets via exports or horizontal FDI, following Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004),
in order to analyze the dynamic impact of offering subsidies to encourage more MNCs. Since the
channel chosen by heterogeneous firms to serve foreign markets depends on whether they earn more
profit from doing so, we can examine how the host country’s consumption is affected in the short run
and long run when a government offers a subsidy, which then improves foreign firms’ profits after
implementing FDI in the host country.
The major contribution of this work to the existing literature on FDI subsidies is that we investigate
the impact of FDI subsidies on the host country’s welfare, including both short‐run and long‐run ef-
fects. We also find that FDI subsidies generate a new problem of delivering welfare deterioration upon
the host economy. In order to examine how welfare in the host country is affected by the use of an FDI
subsidy, we analytically explore the effects of this subsidy in Section 3, focusing on a change in the
host country’s consumption. If firms are heterogeneous in their productivity levels, then a small FDI
subsidy only induces the most productive foreign exporters to switch to conduct FDI and generates a
selection effect of lifting consumption in the host country owing to the consumption gain from luring
more MNCs, which exceeds the consumption loss from financing such a subsidy.3
However, an FDI
subsidy not only increases the ex‐ante profitability of potential entrants to the foreign market but also
transfers the profits from the host country’s firms with relatively lower productivity to foreign firms
FIGURE 1 World foreign direct investment inflows. Source: UNCTAD, FDI/MNE database (www.unctad.org/
fdist atistics) [Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
|
1429
WU et al.
implementing FDI in the host country. The new problem stemming from the reallocation of profits
among firms makes the host country’s market become a less attractive location for prospective en-
trants. Only a few potential entrants would enter the host market, leading to a reduction in the number
of firms engaged in production in that market. The decreases in total profit (returned to equity holders
as dividends) and wage income reduce consumption in the host country.
Section 4 examines the welfare implications of subsidies used to reduce the costs of executing FDI
in the host country. Although the selection effect and the labor switching effect induce a consumption
gain for the host country immediately, the profit shifting effect gradually offsets the consumption gain
and even reverses the initial change in the host country’s consumption in the long run. It implies that
using a fixed cost subsidy plan to attract more MNCs delivers a welfare gain for the host country by
partially counteracting the inefficiency arising from the higher fixed cost preventing some foreign
firms to serve the host economy directly through FDI, but it also generates a new problem leading to
a long‐run deterioration of welfare in the host country. Moreover, we show that a subsidy used for re-
ducing the variable costs of production delivers a greater consumption gain than a fixed cost subsidy,
but also leads to a more severe situation in the reallocation of firms’ profits.
We finally discuss the case that the government has to subsidize all domestic producers if it is not
allowed to discriminate between home and foreign firms producing in the domestic market when of-
fering a subsidy program. Since home firms have the incentive to pretend to be foreign firms when the
government is looking to attract more FDI by offering subsidies to foreign firms, it creates difficulty
for the government to only subsidize the foreign firms. Our analysis in Section 5 closely relates to the
work of Pflüger and Südekum (2013), who examine how subsidies used to reduce the sunk entry costs
of domestic producers in a Melitz‐type model affect the welfare. In their paper, subsidizing all domes-
tic producers’ sunk entry costs encourages more prospective entrants to produce in the domestic mar-
ket. Thus, more goods are produced and sold at lower prices along with the increase in the number of
higher productive firms, delivering welfare improvement for the domestic country. Instead of used to
reduce domestic firms’ entry costs, we discuss that subsidies used to increase the profits of domestic
producers’ production help lure more firms to manufacture in the domestic market. By attracting new
entrants, such a subsidy policy counteracts the profit shifting effect and delivers welfare improvement
to the host country. However, it may encourage too many prospective entrants to engage in the market,
resulting in inefficient resource allocation and welfare deterioration.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the model. Section 3 analyzes
the effect of subsidies for FDI. Section 4 describes the impulse responses of policy interventions.
FIGURE 2 Changes in national investment policies, 2002–2016. Source: UNCTAD [Colour figure can be
viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT