Fool's gold or value for money? The link between abnormal audit fees, audit firm type, fair‐value disclosures, and market valuation

AuthorUlrike Stefani,Ulf Mohrmann,Jan Riepe
Published date01 July 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijau.12155
Date01 July 2019
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Fool's gold or value for money? The link between abnormal
audit fees, audit firm type, fairvalue disclosures, and market
valuation
Ulf Mohrmann
1
|Jan Riepe
2
|Ulrike Stefani
1
1
Department of Economics, University of
Konstanz, Konstanz, Germany
2
Department of Banking, EberhardKarls
University Tuebingen, Tuebingen, Germany
Correspondence
Ulf Mohrmann, Chair of Accounting,
Department of Economics, University of
Konstanz, Box 142, 78457 Konstanz,
Germany.
Email: ulf.mohrmann@unikonstanz.de
We analyze whether the audit firm type and abnormal audit fees are associated with
the market valuation of banks' fairvalue assets. Our results indicate that different
auditor types use different strategies when auditing fair values. First, we show that
Big 4 auditors restrict the Level 3 valuations to the most illiquid assets. Thus, those
banks audited by a Big 4 auditor have a lower proportion of Level 3 assets. Second,
the market discount on the Level 3 assets is higher for the banks audited by a Big 4
auditor than for those audited by a nonBig 4 auditor. Third, the discount on the
Level 3 portfolios of banks with nonBig 4 auditors is higher if the unexpected
audit fees are high. Thus, nonBig 4 auditors seem to allow more highuncertainty
valuations but charge a risk premium. We find similar effects for industryspecialist
auditors.
KEYWORDS
audit fees, audit firm size, banks, fairvalue accounting
1|INTRODUCTION
The idea of fairvalue accounting (FVA) is to increase the relevance of
the information contained in financial statements and, consequently,
to reduce the information asymmetries between the firm's managers
and outside parties. However, applying marktomodel (socalled
Level 3 valuations) instead of using market prices opens up the
opportunity to report high book values although the underlying asset
values decrease (Kothari & Lester, 2012; Milbradt, 2012). Accordingly,
Laux and Leuz (2010) argued that the FVA loses several of its
favorable features when market prices are not available.
The concerns surrounding opportunistic marktomodel valua-
tions might be alleviated by the statutory auditor because his/her
role is to assure the appropriate classification of an asset within
the fairvalue hierarchy and to confirm the quality and soundness
of the valuation models used for the assets contained in Levels 2
and 3 of the fairvalue hierarchy. Thus, the quality of the audit
should affect the link between firms' market values and their book
values. In this vein, Song, Thomas, and Yi (2010) showed that the
market discount on Level 3 assets is less pronounced in those firms
with a higher corporate governance score. In this paper, we focus on
the auditors' strategies to deal with the valuation risk inherent in
marktomodel valuations. These strategies are important for evalu-
ating the auditors' impact on FVA.
Auditors might increase the quality of FVA through two channels.
First, to restrict overvaluations, auditors might enforce that more rep-
resentative assumptions are used in the valuation models. This
strategy would directly reduce the information risk of Level 3 fair
values and, hence, would increase the reliability of Level 3 fair values.
However, it is unclear whether this is a realistic option, given the com-
plexity of the models (Bratten, Gaynor, McDaniel, Montague, & Sierra,
2013; Christensen, Glover, & Wood, 2012; Martin, Rich, & Wilks,
2006). Second, a highquality auditor might improve the precision of
the classification of assets as either Level 2 or Level 3 by requiring
the usage of market inputs whenever possible (Level 2) and by
restricting the Level 3 category to the most illiquid assets. This
strategy might indirectly increase the reliability of the fairvalue mea-
surements if it facilitates the identification of the risk related to Level 3
fair values. Moreover, a more restrictive classification would reduce
auditor exposure to audit risk. Botosan, Carrizosa, and Huffman
Received: 22 December 2016 Revised: 27 November 2018 Accepted: 24 February 2019
DOI: 10.1111/ijau.12155
Int J Audit. 2019;23:181203. © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltdwileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijau 181
(2012) presented anecdotal evidence that auditors use this approach.
Alternatively, auditors might accept the higher audit risk contained in
Level 3 valuations and charge a risk premium as compensation. This
option differs from the first two strategies because it does not affect
the quality of the FVA.
Based on a sample of 363 US banks and 1,073 bankyear observa-
tions from 2008 to 2011, we explore the (combined) effect of auditor
type and abnormal audit fees (which are observable and relevant char-
acteristics of the audit) on the credibility of discretionary asset valua-
tions. The banking sector provides an ideal setting for analyzing the
association between the banks' fairvalue assets and their market
values because FVA is more important than in other industries. Thus,
the financial sector contains a large crosssectional variation in the
exposure to different valuation inputs (i.e., Level 1, Level 2, and
Level 3).
We focus on two observable characteristics of the audit that
should affect the association between banks' fairvalue assets and
their market values. First, we analyze the effect of the auditor type
as measured by the Big 4/nonBig 4 dichotomy. The auditor size is
often seen as a proxy for audit quality (Becker, DeFond, Jiambalvo,
& Subramanyam, 1998; Francis, Maydew, & Sparks, 1999). Moreover,
the fact that the relative bargaining power of the Big 4 auditors is
higher than that of the nonBig 4 auditors might affect their strategy
choice. Second, we explore the role of the abnormal audit fees that
capture either (1) the additional effort of the auditor (Blankley, Hurtt,
& MacGregor, 2012; Eshleman & Guo, 2014; Krishnan, Sami, & Zhang,
2005; Mitra, Deis, & Hossain, 2009), (2) a potential risk premium
charged by the audit firm (see Hay, Knechel, & Wong, 2006, and the
literature cited therein), or (3) the level of auditorclient bonding
(Asthana & Boone, 2012; Choi, Kim, & Zang, 2010). If auditors
improve the reliability of the valuation models by exerting more audit
effort, the abnormal audit fees should reflect higher quality. In that
sense, the higher price for the audit is valuable for the investors. If,
however, auditors just charge a risk premium or if higher fees indicate
bonding, the higher price charged for the audit does not provide
additional benefits for the investors because it does not indicate an
increased reliability of the fairvalue measurement. Given that
according to prior research (e.g., Higgs & Skantz, 2006)investors
perceive positive abnormal audit fees as an indication for high
audit quality, these additional audit fees are misleading, and thus only
fool's gold.
To account for the endogenous formation of the auditorclient
pairs, we run all our tests for the full sample and for a reduced sample
based on propensity score matching. We find qualitatively similar
results for both samples. Specifically, we find a significantly negative
link between the Big 4 indicator and the proportion of Level 3 assets;
that is, banks with Big 4 auditors have lower shares of Level 3 assets.
Turning to Tobin's Q, we find that the proportion of Level 3 assets is
negatively related to the banks' market valuations. The Big 4 indicator
has a positive main effect, indicating that audits conducted by the
Big 4 are regarded as audits of higher quality. The discount on the
Level 3 assets is more pronounced for the Big 4 auditors. However,
this higher discount does not mean that Big 4 auditors provide audits
of lower quality. Combined with our first result (i.e., banks with Big 4
auditors have lower shares of Level 3 assets), the Big 4 auditors
appear to restrict the usage of the Level 3 valuations to the most illiq-
uid assets and enforce the usage of the Level 2 category instead,
which has, on average, superior information quality. In doing so, they
allow a better identification of the information risk included in the
financial statements. If we evaluate the total fairvalue portfolio (for
which the classification decision is irrelevant), we find a higher valua-
tion for the banks with Big 4 auditors, which is again an indication
that the perceived audit quality is higher for the Big 4. The nonBig 4
auditors, in contrast, allow the Level 3 valuations to a larger extent
and, as a consequence, the assets' riskiness is, on average, lower.
We find a significantly negative association between the interaction
of the abnormal audit fees and the Level 3 assets and Tobin's Q,
whereas the coefficient on the interaction term is nonsignificant in
the Big 4 subsample. That is, the investors' risk assessments of the
Level 3 assets is positively associated with the abnormal audit fees
if a nonBig 4 auditor audits the bank, which favors the interpretation
of the abnormal audit fees as a risk premium. In the robustness
checks, we use the auditors' industry specializations as our proxy
for auditor type and find results that are similar to those for the Big 4
auditors.
Our results are also economically significant. The Big 4 auditors
restrict the Level 3 holdings by around one third of the Level 3 hold-
ings of the banks audited by a nonBig 4. Moreover, an increase in
the abnormal audit fees of one standard deviation leads to a Level 3
discount that is 42% higher than for the average bank. Although the
book value of the Level 3 assets is small in magnitude, Level 3 assets
severely affect the market value of equity due to the banks' high lever-
age ratios. The median ratio of the Level 3 assets to the market value
is 20%.
Our findings are in line with the argument that audit firms with
different characteristics apply different strategies: The highquality
auditors (i.e., Big 4 auditors) limit their audit risk by restricting the
use of the Level 3 valuations, and, therefore, the reported proportion
of these valuations reflects the assets' riskiness. In contrast, the non
Big 4 auditors seem to be unable or unwilling to constrain the usage
of the Level 3 category (i.e., the Level 3 assets also contain assets that
could be classified as Level 2, but they would probably have a lower
value if measured using market inputs). These auditors, rather, charge
additional audit fees as a compensation for the higher risk contained in
the potentially overreported values of the Level 3 assets. This results
in a negative combined effect of abnormal audit fees and the Level 3
assets for the banks audited by a nonBig 4 auditor. Supplementary
analyses reinforce the validity of this interpretation over possible
alternative explanations, like highquality auditors avoiding accepting
those clients with high levels of Level 3 fair values.
Our paper contributes to the literature in several ways. First, our
results indicate that different auditor types use different strategies
when auditing banks' fairvalue portfolios. In doing so, we contribute
to the literature on the determinants of the use of Level 3 fair values.
Botosan et al. (2012) presented early evidence on different frictions
(e.g., inadequate understanding of the requirements of Statement of
182 MOHRMANN ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT