Financial integration and the Great Leveraging

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1649
Published date01 January 2019
Date01 January 2019
Received: 15 May 2016 Revised: 26 February 2018 Accepted: 26 June 2018
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1649
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Financial integration and the Great Leveraging
Daniel Carvalho
Banco de Portugal, Lisbon, Portugal
Correspondence
Daniel Carvalho, Banco de Portugal, Rua
Francisco Ribeiro 2 1150-165 Lisbon,
Portugal.
Email:
daniel.sousa.carvalho@bportugal.pt
JEL Classification: E51, F30, G15
Handling Editor: Taylor Mark
Abstract
This paper studies the joint dynamics of international capital flows and
domestic credit and money growth. It finds a strong statistical relationship
between cross-border flows and the decoupling of these two variables—the
Great Leveraging—a stylized fact documented for several economies in the past
decades, due to faster credit than money growth, and associated with the expan-
sion of banks nonmonetary liabilities. Results indicate that, in addition to the
equity/debt breakdown, it is important to split capital flows according to the
domestic recipient sectors: banking sector flows display, in general, a stronger
correlation with the growth of credit and with its excess growth over money.
Furthermore,thecountry'sFXregimealsoplaysarole,asmoneyholdingstend
to be less responsive to cross-border capital flows in fixed FX regimes. In broad
terms, this approach sheds light on the mechanisms through which the inter-
national banking activity might have consequences for the composition of the
domestic aggregate bank balance sheet.
KEYWORDS
capital flows, credit and money, financial integration, financial stability
1INTRODUCTION
Cross-border capital flows and, more generally, financial
integration, interact with domestic credit growth via dif-
ferent channels. On the one hand, capital inflows provide
the resident banking sector with more resources which
can be channeled to domestic credit provision. On the
other hand, capital flows exert an upwardpressure on asset
prices, generating wealth effects, which can be translated
into higher consumption and demand for credit—see, for
instance, Aizenman and Jinjarak (2009), Sá and Wieladek
(2010), and Vásquez-Ruíz (2012). Furthermore, higher
asset values improve household and corporate balance
sheets, boosting collateral values and, in that fashion, may
facilitate the access to credit.
The outburst of the global financial crisis has high-
lighted the need to better understand the connection
between credit growth and financial stability.To the extent
that surges in international capital flows have commonly
been associated with periods of rapid credit growth, they
too have been linked to the likelihood and magnitude of
crises. Examples of studies in this area include Mendoza
and Terrones(2008) and Calderon and Kubota (2012), who
argue that credit booms tend to follow periods of high cap-
ital inflows. In contrast, Sá (2006) does not find evidence
of a causal relationship between both variables. Reinhart
and Reinhart (2008) examine the links between capital
flows and financial crises and draw unconditional proba-
bilities of a crisis given episodes of capital flow bonanzas.
Against the backdrop of the global financial crisis, Lane
and Milesi-Ferretti (2012) study the process of external
adjustment and conclude that, in the pre-crisis period,
countries with higher current account deficits than would
be explained by underlying economic fundamentals expe-
rienced sharper corrections once the crisis erupted.
Recent studies have explored in more detail the relation
between private credit growth and different types of inter-
national capital flows. Lane and McQuade (2014) show
54 © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe Int J Fin Econ. 2019;24:54–79.
CARVALHO 55
that the instrument composition is relevant in this context:
although debt flows exhibit a strong covariation pattern
with private domestic credit growth, the same is not the
case regarding equity flows. More recently, Igan and Tan
(2015) investigate a deeper flow decomposition and find
that foreign direct investment (FDI), portfolio, and other
investment flows have distinct implications for corporate
and household credit.
Despite the body of research on the relationship between
cross-border finance and private domestic credit, to my
knowledge, the literature is yet to explore how financial
integration affects money holdings. The main contribu-
tion of this paper is to extend the previous literature by
assessing how not only the different types of capital flows
but also their domestic recipient sectors interact with both
domestic credit and money holdings.
The relevance of putting together the asset and liability
sides of the banking sector balance sheet in an integrated
manner is further strengthened by the evidence by Schu-
larik and Taylor (2012) of two distinct periods concerning
the dynamics of credit and money. Using a groundbreak-
ing historical dataset, they describe how money and credit
were growing at roughly the same pace since the end of
the Second World Waruntil the early 1970s but, from that
period on, credit grew faster than money. This decoupling
between the two variables—labeled the Great Leverag-
ing by Taylor (2012)—was achieved by the fast expansion
of banks' nonmonetary liabilities, such as long-term debt
securities, which enabled them to grant credit beyond
their deposit base, and can be seen as a measure of
banking sector leverage. Furthermore, based on the cri-
sis classifications in Bordo, Eichengreen, Klingebiel, and
Martinez-Peria (2001), they providethe link between faster
credit growth and crises, by noting that the decoupling
between credit and money went hand in hand with a resur-
gence of these episodes since the 70s—in contrast, there
were barely any crisis episodes before that. Moreover,they
show that credit is a predictor of crises, whereas money is
not. Their intuition for this result is that credit is a more
encompassing measure of bank balance sheets as it cap-
tures features such as leverage and nonmonetary liabilities
which money does not.1
I rely on the monetary presentation of the balance
of payments to track how cross-border flows affect
domestic monetary holdings. In a nutshell, it estab-
lishes a statistical link between balance of payments
flows of the different resident sectors—specifically, bank-
ing or money-issuing and nonbanking or money-holding
sectors—and monetary aggregates. Furthermore, to the
extent that cross-border banking activity is generally seen
as a key driver in credit funding, focusing on the sec-
toral decomposition of flows is also relevant from that
perspective—on the role of global banks, how they oper-
ate and provide liquidity worldwide, see Cetorelli and
Goldberg (2011; 2012), Bruno and Shin (2013), McCauley
(2012) and Niepmann (2013).
To formally assess the relationship between, on the one
hand, credit, money, and the ratio between credit and
money and, on the other hand, banking and nonbanking
sector cross-border capital flows, a cross-sectional econo-
metric specification is carried out, for a group of countries
encompassing OECD members plus other mostly Asian
and Latin American countries. Importantly, the goal is to
determine the covariation patterns of these variables and,
therefore, inferring causality is, in this case, not possible
and left for future research.
More specifically, I ask two main questions: (a) What
is the comovement of capital flows to money-issuing and
money-holding sectors and the growth of domestic credit,
broad money, and the ratio between these two variables
and (b) could this comovement be dependent on the FX
regime of the recipient country? The second question fol-
lows from the evidence in Magud, Reinhart, and Vesper-
oni (2014) that countries with fixed FX regimes tend to
attract more capital from abroad and experience larger
credit expansions than countries with floating FX regimes.
I also ask a third question that naturally emerges from
the previous two: Is it the case that both the sectoral and
instrument composition of flows are relevantto fully assess
the relationship between cross-border flows and credit and
money?
Results indicate that, indeed, there is a differenti-
ated comovement of cross-border flows according to not
only the domestic recipient sectors but also the instru-
ment composition and the growth of credit and money:
While banking sector debt flows significantly and strongly
comove with the decoupling of credit and money—they
display a strong positive covariation with credit growth
but not with money growth—nonbanking sector debt
flows only weakly comove with growth in the credit to
money ratio, likely because there is a coincidence of strong
comovement of these flows with both credit and money
growth. Regarding equity flows, although both the flows
of the banking and nonbanking sectors comove with the
growth of the ratio of credit to money, those of the former
do so on account of a negative comovement with money
growth—a denominator effect—whereas those of the lat-
ter on account of positive comovement with credit—a
numerator effect. Furthermore, the country's FX regime
also matters: There is no evidence of statistically signif-
icant positive correlation of capital flows with money
growth in fixed FX as opposed to floating FX regimes. In
a medium to longer term perspective, using a multiyear
period approach, only banking sector flows comove with
credit and the credit to money ratio and only those of
the nonbanking sectors comove with money. Finally, the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT