Exports of primary goods and human capital accumulation

AuthorCem Karayalcin,Yulin Hou
Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12428
Date01 November 2019
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:1371–1408. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie
|
1371
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Since the 1960s, many developing countries have experienced export‐led growth. Export expansion
has increased the skill premium in some developing countries. For instance, with the integration into
the global economy, the return to skill and the percentage of the population with higher levels of
education grew markedly in China and India. In some countries, however, enrollment rates remain
still low at higher levels of education. For example, on average, only 11% of the population aged 15
and above in Latin America have enrolled in tertiary education in 2010.1
How does one account for
the higher level of human capital accumulation in some countries and persistent stagnation in others
Received: 9 October 2018
|
Revised: 7 April 2019
|
Accepted: 30 May 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12428
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Exports of primary goods and human capital
accumulation
YulinHou1
|
CemKarayalcin2
Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no new data were created or analyzed in this study.
1Zhongnan University of Economics and
Law, Wuhan, China
2Florida International University, Miami,
Florida
Correspondence
Yulin Hou, School of Business
Administration, Zhongnan University
of Economics and Law, Wuhan, China
430073.
Email: yulinhou6@yahoo.com
Abstract
Many developing countries have experienced export‐led
growth in the last half century. This paper asks whether
the content of what economies export matters for human
capital accumulation. We construct a small open economy
model and find that expansion of primary exports can harm
human capital accumulation if the economy is initially al-
locating significant resources to the production of primary
goods. We then test this prediction empirically using Latin
American data over the period 1965 to 2010 and find ro-
bust evidence in support of the hypothesis that a shift to-
wards primary exports reduces human capital accumulation.
Given the importance of the latter for long‐run growth, our
results suggest a potential role for policy intervention.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F16; J24; O12
1372
|
HOU and KaRaYaLCIn
during the export‐led growth period? Does the content of what economies export matter for human
capital accumulation?
This paper explores the trade–human capital nexus by focusing on changes in the exports of pri-
mary goods. We argue that expansion of primary exports can harm human capital accumulation if the
economy is initially allocating significant resources to primary goods production. Briefly, the effect of
international trade on educational acquisition depends on a country’s initial production specialization
pattern. When an economy has a strong comparative advantage in primary goods production, export ex-
pansion reinforces its traditional specialization patterns in the production of unskilled intensive goods.
The associated fall in the demand for skilled labor reduces the incentives to invest in human capital,
slowing down skill upgrading in the primary sector and transition to the modern sector. Therefore,
export expansion in primary goods can slow down the progress of human capital accumulation.
To understand the role of export structure in generating differences in human capital accumula-
tion, we develop a small open economy model of agriculture and manufacture sectors that lasts for
two periods. The analysis demonstrates that an exogenous increase in the relative world price of the
agricultural good can reduce the levels of human capital accumulation if the share of manufacturing
employment is initially less than a critical level. In other words, if the initial agricultural employment
and output are higher than a critical value, export expansion of agricultural goods may act as a positive
demand shock for unskilled labor. Naturally, this trend increases the relative return to unskilled labor
and reduces the incentives to invest in human capital. As a result, over time the share of skilled work-
ers in the labor force declines. This framework highlights an economy’s initial production composition
and exogenous trade shocks that result in the different levels of education acquisition.
The Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) region provides a perfect setting to study the effects
of primary exports on human capital accumulation. Unlike most industrial countries and some de-
veloping countries, an important characteristic of LAC is the large share of primary goods in their
exports. Over the period from 1965 to 2010, the average share of primary exports in total merchandise
exports across LAC countries was around 59%.2
In particular, in the 2000s, some LAC countries
experienced an impressive trade boom in primary exports. For instance, according to the 2016 Latin
American Economic Outlook (Organisation for Economic Co‐operation and Development [OECD]/
Development Bank of Latin America [CAF]/United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America
and the Caribbean [ECLAC], 2015), in the period 2001 to 2010, mining and fossil fuels exports from
Latin America grew at an impressive 16% annually, followed by agricultural products at 12%.
In this paper, we document that the effects of export expansion in primary goods on human capi-
tal accumulation are negative and significant across countries in LAC over the period 1965 to 2010.
The results are robust to the consideration of many control variables and alternative measures of
educational attainment. Furthermore, to address the potential endogeneity of export structure, we use
resource discoveries and international primary goods export price index as instruments for primary
exports to provide further evidence of causality. The two‐sided least squares (TSLS) results are consis-
tent with our panel findings. Overall, these suggest that the specific characteristics of export structure
in LAC can explain the persistent stagnation of its human capital accumulation in the period from
1965 to 2010. Finally, we find evidence that a shift towards primary exports exacerbated the education
inequality in LAC over the same period.
This paper is related to a large literature addressing the trade–human capital nexus in a variety
of contexts. First, this paper provides evidence in support of models of trade with endogenous skill
acquisition (e.g., see Findlay & Kierzkowski, 1983; Foster & Rosenzweig, 1996; Galor & Mountford,
2008). These models predict that international trade will increase the return to the abundant factor
in a given economy. For example, Galor and Mountford (2008) argue that international trade has
played an asymmetrical role in the human capital accumulation between industrial economies and
|
1373
HOU and KaRaYaLCIn
nonindustrial economies. They suggest that in industrial economies, international trade has enhanced
the specialization in the skilled‐labor intensive goods production, which naturally raised the demand
for skilled workers and contributed to investment in education. However, in nonindustrial economies,
the expansion of international trade has generated less demand for skilled workers and fewer incen-
tives to invest in human capital.
Secondly, this paper complements studies that delineate the evolution in educational attainment
across countries. Easterly (2007) and Galor, Moav, and Vollrath (2009) argue that inequality in land
ownership is a key factor for human capital accumulation. Gallego (2010) shows that the degree of
democratization has played a positive role in the development of primary education, and political
decentralization has a significant impact in higher levels of education. Hendricks (2010) suggests that
the majority of the variation in educational attainment across countries is due to within‐industry vari-
ation rather than industry composition. Restuccia and Vandenbroucke (2013, 2014) find that wage and
life expectancy have played an essential role in explaining the trends in hours of work and educational
attainment of the United States over the period from 1870 to 1970.
Finally, this paper also contributes to the growing literature examining the effects of openness on edu-
cational attainment. In the context of India, Shastry (2012), Jensen (2012), and Oster and Steinberg (2013)
all find that the arrival of information technology service jobs had a positive influence on educational
attainment in India. Similarly, Heath and Mobarak (2012) provide evidence that new job opportunities in
garment factories in Bangladesh improved girls’ educational attainment. Atkin (2016) finds that export ex-
pansion in less‐skilled manufacturing in Mexico increased the school drop‐out rate during the period from
1986 to 2000. Li (2018) argues that high/low skill export shocks increase/decrease both high school and
college enrollment in China over the period from 1990 to 2005. In general, these studies focus exclusively
on specific sectors in a relatively small number of locations. One recent paper, by Blanchard and Olney
(2017), focuses on the role of types of sectoral growth in influencing educational attainment. The paper uses
panel data from 102 countries and argues that the change in the composition of a country’s exports is the
key demand‐side driver of education. We differ most importantly from Blanchard and Olney (2017) in that
we focus on exports of primary goods in LAC countries and highlight the initial production specialization
pattern. Furthermore, we use alternative instrumental variables, namely, resource discoveries and the inter-
national primary good export price index, to proxy the export expansion in primary goods. Finally, we pro-
vide evidence on the effect of primary exports on the education inequality and offer a potential explanation.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section introduces a small open economy
model. Section 3 presents data and the corresponding descriptive statistics. Section 4 provides the
empirical analysis. Section 5 pursues a variety of extensions. Section 6 concludes.
2
|
THE MODEL
We start by developing a small open economy model in this section to guide our thinking for the
empirical work that follows. We consider a small open economy that lasts for two periods and is
populated by a constant number of identical individuals. Competitive firms in the economy produce
two final goods: an agricultural good and a manufactured good, both of which are tradable. It is also
assumed that there is no international lending or borowing.3
We now turn to a detailed analysis of firm
and individual behaviors.
2.1
|
Firms
Firms produce the two final goods by employing labor as the only input. In the agriculture sector firms
use unskilled workers. We posit the following production function for agricultural good:

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT