Eurozone cycles: An analysis of phase synchronization

AuthorSana Hussain,Brigitte Granville
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1576
Date01 April 2017
Published date01 April 2017
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Eurozone cycles: An analysis of phase synchronization
Brigitte Granville | Sana Hussain
Queen Mary University of London, Mile End
Road, London E1 4NS, UK
Correspondence
Brigitte Granville, Queen Mary University of
London, Mile End Road, London E1 4NS,
UK.
Email: b.granville@qmul.ac.uk
JEL Classification: C14; E32; E44
Abstract
This paper analyses synchronization, both across and between business and
financial cycles (growth and classical) in a subset of 10 countries representative of
the Economic and Monetary Union. Employing an extended data set from 1960 to
2013, we find evidence of synchronization across financial cycles. In case of
business cycles, we find contrasting results: There is significant synchronization
across growth cycles but no evidence of a common classical cycle. This confirms,
first, that economic and financial variables in the Economic and Monetary Union
behave differently and, second, that synchronization in business cycles arises from
synchronized deviations from the trend, but the underlying macroeconomic
fundamentals are not in synch. Furthermore, we adopt a novel approach to break
down our full sample period into smaller subperiods to follow the evolution of
synchronization over time. Our results highlight the role played by the monetary
union in further increasing macroeconomic divergences.
KEYWORDS
business cycles,concordance, Eurozone, financialcycles, macroeconomic divergences/monetary policy,
timefrequencyanalysis
1|INTRODUCTION
This paper evaluates business and financial cycle synchroni-
zation in a subset of 10 countries representative of Europe's
Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) for the period
19602013. Employing an extended dataset covering periods
both before and after the introduction of the euro, we exam-
ine both classical and growth cycles in order to analyse syn-
chronization in recessions and expansions, as well as
synchronization, in highand lowgrowth periods. In contrast
to the existing literature, this allows us to further probe
whether the observed patterns of synchronization arise from
a comovement of output level or output gap, that is, whether
it is the classical cycle that exhibits synchronization or the
growth cycle. Our paper also augments the existing studies
by examining synchronization in smaller subperiods to fol-
low its evolution more closely. We adopt a novel approach
in breaking down the full sample time series into smaller sub-
periods based on graphical analysis of the mean and standard
deviation of the relevant time series.
Our aim is to assess whether with the introduction of the
euro, EMU members spend more time in the same cyclical
phase as was posited by some authors at the time of its incep-
tion such as Artis and Zhang (1997) and Frankel and Rose
(1998). Others such as De Haan et al., (2008: 265) have
argued that the monetary union can result in less business
cycle synchronization as the exchange rate can no longer
act as a shock absorbing mechanism, meaning that all adjust-
ments must be borne by the real economy, with Eurozone
(EZ) members relying on either export (Germany) or domes-
tic demand (Spain and France) as drivers of economic recov-
ery (McCarthy, 2006).
This question is of importance in a monetary union as it is
linked to the effectiveness of implementing common counter-
cyclical economic policies in response to the euro crisis to
revive economic growth. If business cycles are not synchro-
nized, a onesizefitsall monetary policy may not be optimal
as some countries will be in the contraction phase while others
will be in the recovery phase of theircycles. The existenceof a
common business cycle is under debate (partly because of the
use of different data and methods), but the consensus is that
there is no common business cycle in the EZ and that the eco-
nomic trend is one of divergence rather than convergence
(Gayer, 2007; Hallett & Richter, 2008). De Haan et al.
Received: 4 June 2015 Revised: 26 November 2016 Accepted: 12 February 2017
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1576
Int J Fin Econ. 2017;22:83114. Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe 83
(2008: 266) determine in their business cycle synchronization
survey that business cycles in the EZ are substantially out of
synchand that there is no movement towards the emergence
of a Europeanbusiness cycle.Similarly, Beine, Candelon,
and Hecq (2000) find no common cyclical features in the
EZ, and Kose, Otrok, and Whitman (2003) find no evidence
of a European cycle. Camacho, PerezQuiros, and Saiz
(2006) also conclude that the establishment of the EMU has
not increased the levels of comovement across these econo-
mies. Artis, Marcellino, and Proietti (2005) observe low signs
of synchronization across the EZ.
Any such divergence would affect the sustainability of the
monetary union especially if the dynamics of financial cycles
are considered (Borio, 2014). Therefore, drawing on
Claessens, Kose, and Terrones (2012), we also explore the
interaction between business and financial cycles. The syn-
chronization of business and financial cycles within each
country can magnify fluctuations via a feedback mechanism
where financial variables affect real variables and vice versa
(Claessens et al., 2012). Transmission of this impact via the
common monetary mechanism can then influence the EZ as
a whole. For instance, if economic recessions are accompa-
nied by financial downturns, the adverse impact may be more
severe and prolonged (Claessens et al., 2012). It is, therefore,
of prime importance to further deepen our understanding of
the link between business and financial cycles (Borio,
2014; Claessens et al., 2012; Egert & Sutherland, 2014).
For this reason, our paper also analyses the interaction
between business and financial cycles, which has not been
done exclusively for the EZ before.
Following this introduction, Section 2 presents our data
and methodology. Concordance indices are used to investi-
gate the extent of comovement in economic cycles.
Section 3 examines the synchronization of the different phases
(recessions and expansions) of classical business cycles
(measured by industrial production) across our sample of
EMU members, the different phases (downturns and upturns)
of classical financial cycles (measured by equity prices) across
those same countries participating in EMU, the synchroniza-
tion of the different phases (high rate and low rate) of the
growth version of business and financial cycles, and the con-
cordance between business and financial cycles. We test
whether this comovement or concordance is statistically sig-
nificant and whether it has intensified or diminished over
time. Section 4 provides concluding comments.
2|MEASURING SYNCHRONIZA-
TION IN CYCLES
Observed patterns of synchronization depend on the choice
of measurement methods. The choices involved here con-
cern: the cycle (classical vs. growth and cycles in growth
rates), the concordance (correlatio n vs. concordance index),
and the detrending technique (linear, band pass, or high pass;
Hallett & Richter, 2008: 73). We follow Hodrickand Prescott
(1997: 2) in assuming that no one approach dominates all
the others and that it is best to examine the data from a num-
ber of different perspectives.Our methods consist of, first,
detecting cycles by identifying turning points and, second,
determining synchronization by calculating concordance
indices. This methodology was developed for studying busi-
ness cycles and applied to financial cycles by Claessens
et al. (2012), Drehmann, Borio, and Tsatsaronis (2012) and
Pagan and Sossounov (2003).
For detecting cycles, we first focus on classical cycles,
which consider the level of the underlying time series. Clas-
sical cycles have been defined by Burns and Mitchell
(1946: 3) as the sequential patter n of expansions (the time
period from a trough to a peak) and recessions (the time
period from a peak to a trough) in the level of economic
activity, with the rider that this sequence of change is recur-
rent but not periodic.The Burns and Mitchell rules guided
the National Bureau of Economic Research procedure for
producing the reference dates of the business cycle for the
United States. For classical financial cycles, the expansion
phase is termed an upturn and the contraction phase a down-
turn (Claessens et al., 2012: 180).
Second, we focus on growth cycles, which involve
removing the permanent component (trend) from the under-
lying time series. Growth cycles are defined by Kydland
and Prescott (1990) as the deviation of the variable of interest
from its longterm trend. Although classical and growth
cycles are related, the growth cycle measures the upward
and downward deviation of economic or financial activity
from its longterm trend rather than the level. Therefore, con-
trary to classical cycles, the trend and cyclical components
have to be separated for identifying growth cycles. This
requires identifying the factors determining long run
economic growth from those determining cyclical fluctua-
tions(Stock & Watson, 1999: 9). However, breaking down
the relevant time series into trends and cycles is not easy as
both the trend and cycle influence each other and an appro-
priate filtering technique is required.
2.1 |Data
The data were obtained from the OECD statistics database for
10 countries selected as representative of the presentday EZ:
Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
the Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain.
For business cycles, we use 10 seasonally adjusted
monthly time series of the industrial production (IP) index
from 1960:1 through 2013:12. The data measure volume
changes over time as indices, seasonally adjusted with 2010
as the base year. IP refers to the volume of output generated
84 GRANVILLE AND HUSSAIN
by production units grouped into industrial sectors (such as
mining, manufacturing, and electricity gas and water) in line
with the International Standard Industrial Classification of all
economic activities. We reject the view that IP cannot be used
as a proxy for total output because manufacturing activity
represents less than 20 per cent of aggregate output in the
Eurozone(De Haan et al., 2008: 236) given that most of
the cyclical variation in the EZ economy is explained by
the industrial sector (Gayer, 2007: 2) and a historically
strong correlation between IP and GDP dataGayer (2007:
7) has been observed. Moreover, most of the related analyses
are based on IP data, for example, Artis and Zhang (1997),
Artis, Krolzig, and Toro (2004), Camacho et al. (2006), Har-
ding and Pagan (2006), Inklaar and De Haan (2001), and
Massmann and Mitchell (2004), not only because IP data is
available at a monthly frequency from 1960 but also because
it displays more cyclical sensitivity than gross domestic prod-
uct estimates. This allows greater precision in measuring
business cycles by capturing more of the highfrequency
fluctuations.
In contrast to business cycles, there is no obvious mea-
sure for financial cycles (Borio, 2014). Related literature
identifies financial cycles in three distinct but interdependent
market segments, namely, credit, residential real estate, and
equity prices (Claessens et al., 2012). We follow Pagan and
Sossounov (2003) in using equity prices as they exhibit
greater volatility featuring more upturns and downturns.
These are also available at a monthly frequency for a longer
time period and therefore facilitate greater precision in iden-
tifying cycles. For financial cycles, we consider 10 monthly
time series of the share price index from 1957:1 through
2013:12. The OECD database defines the share price index
as the prices of companies traded on national or foreign stock
exchanges. The share price index is an indicator of fluctua-
tions in the equity market and can be viewed as a proxy for
fluctuations in the overall financial markets. Monthly data
are simple arithmetic averages of the closing daily values
with 2010 as the base year.
2.2 |Identifying turning points
2.2.1 |Classical cycles
For identifying classical cycles, we employ the business
cycle dating algorithm developed by Harding and Pagan
(2002) using the insights of Bry and Boschan (1971) set
out in Table 1. We apply this algorithm to the natural loga-
rithm y
t
of the monthly index of IP Y
t
over the years
19602013 and the natural logarithm p
t
of the monthly index
of share prices P
t
over the years 19572013. Our censoring
rules follow the National Bureau of Economic Research def-
initions: cycles must have a minimum length of 15 months,
phases must have a minimum length of 6 months, and the
window over which local maxima (peaks) and minima
(troughs) are computed is 5 months.
A classical business cycle peak is said to occur at time tif
yt>yt5;yt4yt1
ðÞ
and yt>ytþ1;ytþ2ytþ5

and a trough occurs at time tif
yt<yt5;yt4yt1
ðÞand yt<ytþ1;ytþ2ytþ5

:
Similarly, a classical financial cycle peak occurs at time t
if
pt>pt5;pt4pt1
ðÞand pt>ptþ1;ptþ2ptþ5

and a trough occurs at time tif
pt<pt5;pt4pt1
ðÞand pt<ptþ1;ptþ2ptþ5

:
2.2.2 |Growth cycles
For identifying growth cycles, we first filter y
t
and p
t
before
applying a modified version of the BryBoschan algorithm to
TABLE 1 Bry Boshan (BB) procedure for programmed determina-
tion of turning points
Step Procedure
1. Determination of extremes and substitution of values.
2. Determination of cycles in 12month moving average (extremes
replaced).
A. Identification of points higher (or lower) than 5 months on
either side.
B. Enforcement of alternation of turns by selecting highest of
multiple peaks (or lowest of multiple troughs).
3. Determination of corresponding turns in Spencer curve
(extremes replaced).
A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within 5 months
of selected turn in 12month moving average.
B. Enforcement of minimum cycle duration of 15 months by
eliminating lower peaks and higher troughs of shorter cycles.
4. Determination of corresponding turns in shortter m moving
average of 3 to 6 months, depending on MCD (months of
cyclical dominance).
A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within 5 months
of selected turn in Spencer curve.
5. Determination of turning points in unsmoothed series.
A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within 4 months,
or MCD term, whichever is larger, of selected turn in shortterm
moving average.
B. Elimination of turns within 6 months of beginning and end of
series.
C. Elimination of peaks (or troughs) at both ends ofseries which
are lower (or higher) than values closer to end.
D. Elimination of cycles whose duration is less than 15 months.
E. Elimination of phases whose duration is less than 5 months.
6. Statement of final turning points.
Source: Bry and Boschan (1971, p.21; table 1)
GRANVILLE AND HUSSAIN 85

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT