Estimating the Cost‐of‐Equity Capital Using Empirical Asset Pricing Models

Published date01 March 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irfi.12179
Date01 March 2019
AuthorChris Kirby
Estimating the Cost-of-Equity
Capital Using Empirical Asset
Pricing Models*
CHRIS KIRBY
Department of Finance, University of North Carolina Charlotte at Charlotte, NC
ABSTRACT
Empirical asset pricing models seek to capture characteristic-based patterns
in the cross-section of average stock returns. I propose a new approach for
constructing these models, and investigate its performance with respect to
estimating the cost-of-equity capital. Using a model that accounts for the
cross-sectional relation between ve characteristics and average stock returns,
I obtain cost-of-equity estimates that outperform those produced by the
Fama-French ve-factor model in out-of-sample tests. Because the proposed
approach builds directly on standard cross-sectional regression techniques, it
provides complete exibility in choosing the rm characteristics used to for-
mulate the cost-of-equity estimates.
JEL Code: G12
Accepted: 18 December 2017
I. INTRODUCTION
The cost-of-equity capital (i.e., the expected rate of return on a rms stock)
plays a central role in capital budgeting, rm valuation, portfolio selection, and
a host of other applications. Estimating this quantity is therefore of widespread
interest to academics and practitioners alike. The most commonly used
methods for constructing cost-of-equity estimates are nding the internal rate
of return that equates a rms stock price to the present value of its estimated
expected future cash ows (the internal-cost-of-capital method), and tting lin-
ear asset pricing models to historical stock returns.
1
My analysis focuses on the
latter of these two methods. In particular, I investigate the cost-of-equity esti-
mates produced by linear asset pricing models that are explicitly designed to
capture characteristic-based patterns in average individual stock returns.
* I thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments, and Adriana Cordis for her contributions to
early versions of the paper.
1 Studies that use the former approach include Claus and Thomas (2001), Gebhardt
et al. (2001), Easton (2004), and Hou et al. (2012), while those that use the latter approach
include Elton et al. (1994), Ferson and Locke (1998), Pastor and Stambaugh (1999), Cummins
and Phillips (2005), and Barth et al. (2013).
© 2018 International Review of Finance Ltd. 2018
International Review of Finance, 19:1, 2019: pp. 105154
DOI: 10.1111/ir.12179
The three-factor model of Fama and French (1993), which builds on the
ndings of Fama and French (1992), is the most famous example of such a
specication.
2
It is motivated by cross-sectional regression evidence that two
easily-measured rm characteristics, the market value of equity (ME) and the
book-to-market (B/M) equity ratio, dominate the market beta with respect to
explaining the cross-section of average individual stock returns. To capture this
feature of the historical data, Fama and French (1993) add the returns on two
characteristic-based hedge portfolios to the right-hand side of the market model
regression. By restricting the regression intercept to be zero for every stock, they
obtain an empirical asset pricing model that implies a linear multi-beta repre-
sentation for expected excess stock returns.
Unlike Fama and French (1993), who use cross-sectional regression evidence
to motivate a separate and distinct time-series specication, I focus on the time-
series implications of the cross-sectional regressions themselves. My strategy is
inspired by a connection between cross-sectional regression estimators and the
type of hedge portfolios that are employed in the three-factor model. Building
on the ideas developed by Fama (1976), I demonstrate that each element of the
estimated vector of slope coefcients for a cross-sectional regression specica-
tion is proportional to the return generated by a characteristic-based hedge
portfolio. This insight lies at the core of my approach for constructing empirical
asset pricing models.
To see why cross-sectional regression estimators are closely related to hedge
portfolios, let r
i,t
and x
i,t
denote the stock return of rm ifor period tand some
characteristic of rm ithat is predetermined with respect to period t. The Fama
and MacBeth (1973) methodology for assessing whether the characteristic helps
to explain the cross-section of expected stock returns is simple. Fit a cross-
sectional regression of r
i,t
on x
i,t
for a range of different time periods, and use
the average values of the resulting coefcient estimates to draw inferences. It is
well known that the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator of the slope coef-
cient for a regression of r
i,t
on x
i,t
is simply a weighted sum of the stock returns
used to t the regression. If one has Nstocks in total (e.g., the available number
of NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ rms for period t), then the weight for rm iis
proportional to xi,t^μx,t, where ^μx,t=1=NðÞ
PN
i=1xi,t. It follows, therefore, that
the estimated slope coefcient is the payoff on a zero-cost position in the
Nstocks.
With a little algebra, this zero-cost payoff can be expressed as a scaled version
of the return on a characteristic-based hedge portfolio, that is, the return
obtained by taking a long position in one unit-cost portfolio and a short posi-
tion in another unit-cost portfolio, both of which have nonnegative
characteristic-dependent weights. Consequently, one can show that tting a
cross-sectional regression of r
i,t
on x
i,t
decomposes the stock return for each rm
into a sum of three components, all of which have a simple interpretation. The
2 Other examples include the four-factor model of Carhart (1997), the four-factor model of
Hou et al. (2014), and the ve-factor model of Fama and French (2015).
© 2018 International Review of Finance Ltd. 2018106
International Review of Finance
rst component is the return on an equally weighted portfolio of the Nstocks,
the second is proportional to the return on a characteristic-based hedge portfo-
lio, and the third is a rm-specic residual.
This approach readily generalizes to the case of multiple regressors. Suppose,
for example, that the regressors consist of log ME and the log B/M ratio, as in
Fama and French (1992). It is easy to verify that the estimated slope for log ME
is proportional to the return on a characteristic-based hedge portfolio. To con-
struct the long and short ends of the portfolio, one ts a cross-sectional regres-
sion of log ME on the log B/M ratio, gathers all the rms that have positive
residuals into one group (stocks purchased) and all the rms that have negative
residuals into another group (stocks shorted), and weights the returns of the
rms in each group in proportion to their absolute residuals. Similarly, the esti-
mated slope for the log B/M ratio is proportional to the return on a
characteristic-based hedge portfolio whose long and short ends are constructed
via the reverse regression (log B/M ratio on log ME). Thus the stock return for
each rm can be expressed as a linear function of the return on an equally
weighted portfolio, the returns on two characteristic-based hedge portfolios,
and a rm-specic residual. By averaging each of these components for a given
rm over time, I obtain a regression-based decomposition of the rms average
stock return.
The decompositions of average stock returns obtained by averaging cross-
sectional regressions are exact, that is, they hold by construction for ev ery
rm. However, they can be transformed into empirical asset pricing models by
adopting suitable assumptions. Under the proposed assumptions, specifying
log ME and the log B/M ratio as regressors produces a model that mirrors the
basic structur e of the Fama and Fren ch (1993) three- factor model. Tha t is, it
decomposes the expected excess return for each stock into a linear combina-
tion of the expected excess returns on the market portfolio and two
characteristic-based hedge portfolios. The key distinction between the two
models is how risk is measured. My approach implies that the loadings on the
risk factors are directly linked to the characteristic values. In effect, I obt ain a
modelinwhichtheaveragecharacteristicvaluesserveasobservableproxies
for systematic risk.
The empirical tests focus on a model that uses ve characteristic-based hedge
portfolios as factors. My choice of characteristics is motivated by prior research.
I consider log ME and the log B/M ratio (Fama and French 1992, 1993), and the
ratio of gross prots to total assets (GP/TA). Novy-Marx (2013) shows that the
cross-sectional explanatory power of the GP/TA ratio rivals that of the log B/M
ratio. I also consider two other characteristics from the recent literature: the rate
of growth in total assets (TAG), and the ratio of cash equivalents to total assets
(CH/TA). The former is of interest because the literature reports that capital
investment is inversely related to subsequent stock returns (see, e.g., Titman
et al. 2004; Cordis and Kirby 2015), and TAG provides a comprehensive picture
of a rms investment and disinvestment activities (Cooper et al. 2008). The
© 2018 International Review of Finance Ltd. 2018 107
Empirical Asset Pricing Models

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT