Environmental regulation and love for variety

AuthorLuciana Echazu,Martin Heintzelman
Published date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12382
Date01 February 2019
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:413–430. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
413
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Economists rarely concur so much as on the issue of free trade where we, as a profession, are al-
most entirely in agreement that free trade promotes welfare by increasing economic activity, reducing
prices, and making a larger number of product varieties available to consumers. However, we must
also be concerned about the impact of international trade on the environment, as this is another im-
portant aspect of a society’s well‐being. Similarly, it is important to understand how environmental
regulations affect the gains from trade. Do lower trade barriers result in greater environmental degra-
dation? How does international trade policy interact with environmental regulations set independently
by each country? How does the transboundary nature of environmental degradation affect this inter-
action? The objective of this paper is to shed light into these questions.
We present a theoretical model of trade, based on Krugman’s (1980) new trade theory that in-
corporates the strategic decisions of governments when implementing environmental standards. Our
Received: 18 February 2018
|
Revised: 20 September 2018
|
Accepted: 1 October 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12382
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Environmental regulation and love for variety
Luciana Echazu
|
Martin Heintzelman
David D. Reh School of Business, Clarkson
University, Potsdam, New York
Correspondence
Luciana Echazu, David D. Reh School of
Business, Clarkson University, Potsdam, NY
13699‐5790.
Email: lechazu@clarkson.edu
Abstract
Using a model of monopolistic competition, we examine
the relationship between intra‐industry trade and environ-
mental regulation. The decisions on emission standards set
by each country show strong strategic interactions. In
closed economies regulations act as strategic substitutes,
and in equilibrium there is under‐regulation relative to the
cooperative outcome. Trade liberalization may lead to
stricter or laxer environmental standards, depending on
the consumers’ preference for product variety. In addition,
we show that with open trade environmental regulations
may act as strategic complements and countries may set
environmental standards that are as strict (or stricter) than
those in the cooperative outcome.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
Q56, F12, F18
414
|
ECHAZU And HEInTZELMAn
model portrays two countries and two sectors, one homogeneous (and clean), and one differentiated
(and dirty). The differentiated sector exhibits CES preferences and is characterized by monopolistic
competition. Consumers spend a proportion of their budget on the differentiated good; once countries
open up to trade, this proportion can be regarded as the share of all trade that is intra‐industry. The cen-
tral planner in each country sets the standards for environmental quality, which determines how much
each firm in the differentiated sector must invest in abatement technology. These standards impact the
total number of varieties available for consumption and thus affect welfare in opposite directions: they
decrease it by decreasing the number of varieties, and they increase it by increasing environmental
quality. These standards also affect the levels of both local and global levels of environmental degra-
dation, and are set strategically in a noncooperative game‐theoretic setting.
In our model, when countries are closed to international trade environmental regulations act as
strategic substitutes, each country free rides on the standards set by the other, and in equilibrium
there is under‐regulation and over‐pollution relative to the cooperative equilibrium. Opening to trade
allows domestic and foreign consumers to enjoy a greater variety of imported goods. In this context,
costly environmental regulations generate environmental benefits both locally and globally (a positive
externality leading to strategic substitutability) but they also act as a barrier to trade. Given love for
variety on the consumers’ side, (stricter) environmental regulations also negatively affect consumers
by reducing the varieties enjoyed (a negative externality leading to strategic complementarity). This
means that, under open trade, environmental standards may be strategic complements and, more im-
portantly, that equilibrium regulatory standards may be as strict (and possibly stricter) as those in the
cooperative equilibrium (which itself always entails laxer regulation standards than the cooperative
equilibrium without trade). Open trade is, in this sense, more conducive to globally optimal pollu-
tion levels, although it may result in stricter or laxer standards (relative to autarky) depending on the
strength of consumer preferences for product varieties.
As countries open to trade, economic activity increases, which fosters growth; this brings the additional
consideration of how growth affects the environment. In our model, we consider productivity as an indi-
cator of economic growth and assess how exogenous changes in productivity affect emissions given the
abatement technology available, production and the strategic interaction between countries regarding en-
vironmental regulations. Our results are consistent with the existence of an environmental Kuznets curve.
1.1
|
Relation to previous literature
The relationship between trade and environmental outcomes has been the focus of a large literature
for some time (see for instance Antweiler et al., 2001; Cherniwchan et al., 2017; Cole & Elliott, 2003;
Copeland & Taylor, 1994, 1995, 2004; Halicioglu & Ketenci, 2016; Levinson & Taylor, 2008). While
most of the initial research was based on interindustry trade, there has been an increasing trend in
research on intra‐industry trade, recognizing the vast volume of trade that happens within industries
(see Aralas & Hoehn, 2010; Benarroch & Weder, 2006; Cole & Elliott, 2003; Fung & Maechler,
2007; Gürtzgen & Rauscher, 2000; Haupt, 2006; Levy & Dinopoulos, 2016; Roy, 2017 among oth-
ers). Furthermore, authors are also taking into consideration the strategic interactions among govern-
ments when it comes to environmental regulation, not only because opening to trade brings about
interaction and competition among countries but also because environmental degradation is often of a
transboundary nature. Environmental regulation, in this strategic context, can be regarded as a barrier
to trade or as a way to enhance competitiveness (see Anouliès, 2010; Barrett, 1994; Coconi, 2003;
Hubbard, 2014; Ulph, 1996; Ulph & Ulph, 2007).
Grossman and Krueger (1995) find a peculiar relationship between growth and environmental deg-
radation, which takes the shape of an inverted U. They gave this relationship the term “Environmental

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT