Environmental Goods and Measures for Their Promotion: An Analysis Using a Fair Wage Model

Published date01 December 2016
AuthorYasuyuki Sugiyama,Muneyuki Saito
Date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12157
ENVIRONMENTAL GOODS AND MEASURES FOR THEIR
PROMOTION: AN ANALYSIS USING A FAIR WAGE
MODEL
YASUYUKI SUGIYAMA*Fukui Prefectural University
MUNEYUKI SAITO Nara Prefectural University
Abstract. In this paper, we model a two-sector small open economy with emissions and unemployment
associated with the fair wage effort hypothesis, and investigate the environmental and employment
impact of an emission tax, a subsidy for purchasing environmentalgoods in the downstream polluting
industry, and a subsidy to the upstream eco-industry. We then show that if the eco-industry is skilled
labor intensive relative to the polluting nal goods industry, while a subsidy for purchasing
environmental goods decreases the unemployment rate of unskilled labor, it may increase total
emissions. In contrast, the emission tax and the subsidy to eco-industry rms worsen the
unemployment rate, though both policies decrease total emissions. Hence, if the emission tax is set
equal to the marginal environmental damage, and either a downstream or upstream subsidy is used
to mitigate unskilled unemployment, the optimal subsidy to purchase the goods is positive whereas
the optimal subsidy to the eco-industry is negative, i.e., a tax on the eco-industry.
1. INTRODUCTION
Since the last quarter of the 20th century, eco-industries supplying environmental
goods and services, such as water and air pollution abatement equipment and waste
disposal services, have attracted much attention. According to the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), the global market for the
industry was about US$300 billion in 2000 and was expected to continue to increase
at an annual rate of 5.5 percent.1Indeed, various policies support the continuing
expansion of these industries, including subsidies for the production and purchase
of environmental goods and services.2Hence, considering that environmental goods
and services contribute to both the control and reduction of pollution and facilitate
1See OECD (1996, 2001) for detailed data on the eco-industry.
2For example, the Japanese Ministry of the Environment provides subsidies to a range of projects
for CO2 reduction. These projects include the upgrading of facilities to promote energy savings and
the installation of monitoring equipment.
*Address for Correspondence:Faculty of Economics,Fukui Prefectural University, 4-1-1 Matsuoka-
Kenjojima, Eiheiji Town, Fukui Prefecture, 9101195, Japan. E-mail: sugiyama@fpu.ac.jp. We
are deeply indebted to Kenzo Abe, Naoto Jinji, Yoshifumi Okawa, Morihiro Yomogida, conference
and Kansai Branch workshop participants of the Japan Society of International Economics (JSIE),
joint workshop participants of Nagoya International Economic Study Group (NIESG) and Institute
of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization (IDE-JETRO), and seminar
participants of Kyoto University and Gangneung-Wonju National University for their helpful
comments and discussions. We also wish to thank anonymous referees for constructive and fruitful
comments. Yasuyuki Sugiyama and Muneyuki Saito gratefully acknowledge the nancial support
received from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science under a Grant-in-Aid for Scientic
Research (C): No.15 K03440 and Young Scientists (B): No.23730246, and Young Scientists (B):
No.24730217, respectively. The authors are solely responsible for any errors.
Pacic Economic Review, 21: 5 (2016) pp. 581602
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12157
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
bs_bs_banner
natural resource conservation, a desired outcome of the eco-industry is the
achievement of a cleaner environment without adverse effects on economic viability.
Another reason for promoting eco-industries is the creation of employment.
Unemployment and/or wage inequality have continued to be one of the main
subjects of debate. For example, Krugman (1995) supposed the case where OECD
countries open trade with Newly Industrializing Countries (NICs), and noted that
unemployment worsens in Europe (as a rigid wage economy) and that the wage
gap widens in the US (as a flexible wage economy), though trade is not the primary
cause of these labor market problems.3In these circumstances, many have
welcomed the possible expansion of job opportunities anticipated in the new eco-
industries. Hence, in this paper, we focus attention on environmental goods
produced in eco-industries and analyze the environmental and employment effects
of two subsidy measures used to promote these goods, i.e., subsidies for purchasing
environmental goods and to eco-industry firms, in addition to an emission tax.4
To investigate the impacts in a manner consistent with our primary motivation,
we introduce unemployment associated with the fair wage effort hypothesis.
Akerlof and Yellen (1988, 1990) consider the relationship between effort and
fairness based on social exchange theory in sociology and equity theory in
psychology.5More concretely, worker effort depends on perceived fairness, and
then if the wage workers receive is lower than the fair wage, they reduce their effort
by equating it with their reward, whereas overpayment does not give rise to
excessive effort. By using the effort function from this worker behavior and
supposing that the fair wage of one group is a weighted average of the wage
received by the other group and the own market-clearing wage, they prove that
unemployment arises only among unskilled workers. Subsequently, Kreickemeier
and Nelson (2006) construct a general equilibrium model with fair wages à la
Akerlof and Yellen (1988, 1990) and examine the impact of more egalitarian
preferences, the opening of trade with NICs, and technological change on a trading
economy consisting of Europe and the US with different preferences for fairness.6
Egger and Kreickemeier (2008) investigate the impact of international
fragmentation on fair wage unemployment, and show that if the domestic
production is sufficiently skilled labor intensive overall after fragmentation, the
higher the skilledunskilled endowment ratio, the more domestic unemployment
3Davis (1998a) constructsa model in which Europe and the US exist within the same world economy,
and shows that if trade with NICs opens in the free-tradeequilibrium between them, unemployment
deteriorates further in Europe but not in the US. In the same Europe and US model, Davis (1998b)
analyzes the effectsof technological change on the wage differential and unemployment. Kreickemeier
and Nelson (2006) follow the analytical method in Davis (1998a, 1998b).
4At its 2012 annual meeting, the Asia-Pacic Economic Cooperation (APEC) forum listed 54 items
as environmental goods that contribute to green growth and sustainable development, declaring that
the tariffs applying to these goods should fall to 5 percent or less by the end of 2015. Considering such
practical matters, we suppose environmental goods trade in our model. However, we do not set out
the tariffs on the goods because the promotion of domestic eco-industries is our central concern.
5Prior to these studies, Solow (1979) and Akerlof (1982) consider the role of noneconomic factors,
such as fairness and social norms, as possible factors in determining rigid wages.
6Following Akerlof (1982), Agell and Lundborg (1995) consider a small open fair wage economy where
the effort level of workers depends on the income distribution between labor and capital (more specically,
the wagerental rate ratio), and examine the impact of the change in the relative price of nal goods.
Y. SUGIYAMA AND M. SAITO582
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT