Endogenous timing of moves in Bertrand–Edgeworth triopolies

Date01 December 2016
Published date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12098
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12098
Endogenous timing of moves in Bertrand–Edgeworth
triopolies
Attila Tasn´
adi
We determine the endogenous order of movesin w hichthe fir ms set their prices in the frame-
work of a capacity-constrained Bertrand–Edgeworth triopoly. A three-period timing game that
determines the period in which the firms announce their prices precedes the price-setting stage.
We show that the firm with the largest capacity sets its price first, while the two other firms set
their prices later.Our result extends a finding by Deneckere and Kovenock from duopolies to tri-
opolies. This extension was made possible byHirata’s recent advancements on the mixed-strategy
equilibria of Bertrand–Edgeworth games.
Key wor ds Bertrand–Edgeworth, price leadership, oligopoly, timing games
JEL classification D43, L13
Accepted 13 October 2015
1 Introduction
A challenging question for oligopoly theory and its applications is the determination of the right
order of moves because this influences the market structure and its equilibrium behavior. In this
paper we address the timing problem for price-setting games, in particular, within the framework
of a homogeneous good capacity-constrained Bertrand–Edgeworth triopoly. The key feature of
these price-setting games is that the firms may serve less than the demand they are facing. The
main difficulty with these models is that one has to consider mixed-strategy equilibria since for the
interesting cases there is a lack of equilibrium in pure strategies.1
Deneckere and Kovenock (1992) determined the endogenous order of decisions in a homoge-
neous good Bertrand–Edgeworth duopoly game with capacity constraints. Their result was partially
generalized from duopolies to oligopolies byGangopadhyay (1993) who compared the simultaneous-
move case with the purely sequential-move case, which still did not determine the endogenous order
of moves for the oligopolistic case. The main difficulty in solving the timing problem lies in handling
the mixed-strategy equilibrium of the Bertrand–Edgeworth game. Beckmann (1965), Levitan and
Shubik (1972), Vives (1986), and Cheviakov and Hartwick (2005) determined the mixed-strategy
equilibrium solutions under quite restrictive assumptions such as linear demand or identical firms.
Under more general conditions the mixed-strategy equilibrium has been given in non-closed form
MTA-BCE “Lend¨
ulet” Strategic Interactions Research Group, Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of
Budapest, Budapest, Hungary.Email: attila.tasnadi@uni-corv inus.hu
I am very grateful to an anonymous referee for comments and suggestions which helped to improveprevious versions of
this paper.Financial support from the Hungarian Scientific Research Fund (OTKA K-101224) is gratefully acknowledged.
1For more on Bertrand–Edgeworth games the reader is referred to Vives (1999).
International Journal of Economic Theory 12 (2016) 317–334 © IAET 317
International Journal of Economic Theory
Bertrand–Edgeworth triopolies Attila Tasn´
adi
by Kreps and Scheinkman (1983), Davidson and Deneckere (1986), Osborne and Pitchik (1986),
and Allen and Hellwig (1993) in the duopolistic setting.
The investigation of the triopolistic timing game has been made possible by recent character-
izations of the mixed-strategy equilibrium of capacity-constrained Bertrand–Edgeworth triopolies
by Hirata (2009), and independently by De Francesco and Salvadori (2010). Based on their charac-
terizations, we find that the large-capacity firm will emerge as the endogenous price leader, which
extends a result for the duopolistic case obtained by Deneckere and Kovenock (1992). Timing of
decisions within the price-setting framework usually results in known forms of price leadership, and
therefore we will also relate our results to the dominant firm model of price leadership.
In general, there is a growing literature on endogenous timing of decisions in oligopolies in both
the price-setting and the quantity-setting framework. The first contributions in this direction were
made by Gal-Or (1985), Dowrick (1986), and Boyer and Moreaux(1987) in works that compared the
outcomes of duopoly games with exogenously givenorderings of moves to find out whether the leader
or the follower has a more advantageous position. The recent literature aims to solve the conflict
concerning roles, and determines an endogenous order of moves under certain circumstances. Just
to mention some important works from the large number of contributions, we refer to Hamiltonand
Slutsky (1990), Deneckere and Kovenock(1992), van Damme and Hurkens (1999, 2004), Matsumura
(1999, 2002), Dastidar and Furth (2005), Yano and Komatsubara (2006, 2012), and von Stengel
(2010).
It is worth mentioning that another strand of the literature aims to generalize results from the
Bertrand–Edgeworth duopoly game with deterministic demand to the case of demand uncertainty.
For notable results in this direction we refer to Hviid (1991), Reynolds and Wilson(2000), de Frutos
and Fabra (2011), and Lepore (2012).
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents our framework and
an important lemma. Section 3 considers price-setting games with exogenously given orderings of
moves. Section 4 determines the solution of our three-period timing game. Section 5 contains some
concluding remarks.
2 Framework and preliminary result
Suppose that there are three firms in the market, where we shall denote the set of firms by N=
{1,2,3}. Weassume that the firms have zero unit costs2up to some positive capacity constraints. We
shall denote by kithe capacity constraint of firm iand by K=3
i=1kithe aggregate capacity of the
firms. Let the capacity constraints be ordered decreasingly, and so as to reduce the number of cases
we also assume that the two firms with the smallest capacities have identical capacities, k1>k
2=k3.
We summarize the assumptions imposed on the triopolists’ costfunctions as follows.
Assumption 1 There are three firms on the market with zero unit costs and capacity constraints k1>
k2=k3>0.
We refer to firm 1 as the large firm and to firms 2 and 3 as the small firms. The demand is given by
the function Don which we impose the following restrictions.
2Since we are considering the production-to-order version of the Bertrand–Edgeworth game (that is, production takes
place after the firms’ prices are revealed), the realassumption here is that the firms have identical unit costs.
318 International Journal of Economic Theory 12 (2016) 317–334 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT