Dynamic Moral Hazard and Executive Stock Options

AuthorFrank Yong Wang,Baomin Dong,Guixia Guo
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12017
Published date01 May 2013
Date01 May 2013
DYNAMIC MORAL HAZARD AND EXECUTIVE
STOCK OPTIONS
BAOMIN DONG Henan University
GUIXIA GUO University of International Business and Economics
FRANK YONG WANG*University of International Business and Economics
Abstract. This paper shows that the optimal executive compensation scheme in a dynamic moral
hazard environment is convex in the firm value. This implies that the optimal contract should include
stock options. This is because the private benefit of shirking is increasing in firm value and the
manager’s utility is concave. Therefore, in contrast to the previous literature that takes stock options
in the incentive contract exogenously, we rationalize the optimality of their use endogenously.
Moreover, we show that the optimal amount of stock options (restricted stocks) increases with
agency cost and the executive’s reservation utility, decreases with the degree of risk aversion of the
manager, and increases (decreases) with the firm size.
JEL Classification: C73, D86, G34
1. INTRODUCTION
Executive stock options, as a long-term incentive mechanism, give executives the
right to buy their firm’s shares at a prespecified strike price. Over the past two
decades, the use of stock options has represented a major change in the corpo-
rate governance structure (Holmstrom and Kaplan, 2001). Stock options are
also one of the most frequently used tools in executive compensation schemes
(Hall and Liebman, 1998; Murphy, 1999; Hall and Murphy, 2000, 2002, 2003).
However, with the increasingly extensive use of stock options and with the
rising proportion of option value in executives’ compensation, heated debate has
emerged over the ‘generosity’ of executive stock options, both in academia and
industry. After the global financial crisis in 2008, several financial institutions,
including those who received government bailouts, continued to provide fat
bonuses for their executives. Whether such huge bonuses are worthwhile has
been discussed extensively in the literature. For instance, Meulbroek (2001) and
*Address for Correspondence: School of International Trade and Economics, University of Inter-
national Business and Economics, Beijing 100029, China. E-mail: wangyong9110@gmail.com. The
authors are grateful to an anonymous referee for his insightful comments on an earlier version of the
paper. Guixia Guo is grateful for financial support from the 2011 National Social Science Founda-
tion Major Project (Grant no. 11&ZD007), the 2012 National Natural Science Funds of China for
Young Scholars (Grant no. 71203026), the Humanities and Social Science Research Projects of the
MOE in China (Grant no. 12YJC790047), Program for Innovative Research Team and the ‘211
Program’ in UIBE. Frank Yong Wang is grateful for financial support from the Program for
Innovative Research Team and from the ‘211 Program’ at the University of International Business
and Economics.
bs_bs_banner
Pacific Economic Review, 18: 2 (2013) pp. 259–279
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12017
© 2013 Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
Hall and Murphy (2000, 2002) claim that firms have to compensate their
risk-averse executives with more stock options, because the executives cannot
choose efficient investment portfolios and, thus, significantly undervalue the
stock options.1However, Lambert and Larcker (2004) point out that such
analysis is incomplete, because the incentive role of stock options is neglected.
The essence of the debate is whether executives should be granted stock
options and, if so, what is the optimal amount? No consensus has been reached.
Haugen and Senbet (1981) are among the first to propose stock options as an
instrument to alleviate the conflict between shareholders and managers, but
their focus is on executives’ excessive incentive of entrenchment due to the
issuance of new shares. Therefore, their discussion is more about the issue of
capital structure. In a setting with hyperbolic absolute risk aversion utility and
gamma distribution functions, Hemmer et al. (2000) show that stock options are
a component of the optimal compensation contract only if the executive’s abso-
lute coefficient of risk aversion is decreasing and his or her relative coefficient
of risk aversion is moderate. However, using constant relative risk aversion
(CRRA) utility and lognormal distribution functions, the simulation results of
Dittmann and Maug (2007) predict that the optimal compensation scheme that
does not include stock options can realize the same level of incentive and
executives’ utility at 20% less cost.
In our opinion, the long-run or dynamic nature of moral hazard of the
executives is key for executive stock options plans. Thus, in the current paper,
we use a dynamic or multi-period moral hazard framework to study the optimal
compensation contract. This is in contrast to the aforementioned papers, which
use a static setup in which before the output realization the manager can make
his or her effort decision only once. The dynamic model is better suited for
reality and tailored to address the incentive role of stock options in the long run.
Using a simple binomial output process, we show that the optimal compen-
sation scheme is convex in the firm value. This naturally implies that stock
options should be included in the optimal contract. There are two factors
contributing to the convexity result. The first is that the private benefit of
shirking is increasing in the firm value. Hence, the optimal contract should pay
higher at the margin for a given increase in output. In addition, because the
manager is risk averse, his or her marginal utility for a given increase in payment
is smaller, and, hence, the firm needs to pay more to offset a given amount of
private benefit derived from shirking. Note that the fixed payment plus a linear
piece rate contract prescribed by the traditional principal–agent theory only
yields a linear contract. Given that stock options are financial assets with a
convex payoff structure in reality, they should be included in the optimal com-
pensation contract.
In contrast to the previous literature that exogenously assumes that the com-
pensation contract consists of a base wage, restricted stocks and stock options
(e.g. Lambert and Larcker, 2004; Dittmann and Maug, 2007; Armstrong et al.,
1When granting stock options and restricted stock to executives, there is generally a vesting period
during which the options and stocks cannot be sold out.
B. DONG ET AL.
260
© 2013 Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT