Does Tariff Induce Intellectual Property Right Protection and Reduce Incidence of Piracy?

AuthorDyuti S. Banerjee,Rajat Acharyya
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12263
Date01 May 2017
Published date01 May 2017
Does Tariff Induce Intellectual Property Right
Protection and Reduce Incidence of Piracy?
Rajat Acharyya and Dyuti S. Banerjee*
Abstract
We consider a model with North exporting a copyrighted product to South where there is IPR violation,
and South exports a basic good to North. We examine the impact of North’s imposition of import tariff on
South’s monitoring of IPR violation and the incidence of piracy. If South values IPR compliance “lowly”,
then tariff imposition do not alter the pre-tariff no monitoring equilibrium outcome but unambiguously
raises the incidence of piracy. If IPR compliance is valued “highly” then tariff either switches the equilib-
rium outcome from not monitoring to monitoring or increases its rate. However, the incidence of piracy
may increase.
1. Introduction
Developed countries often use tariff and non-tariff barriers as threat instruments to
induce enforcement of Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs)
in their developing country trade partners. For example, Morrison (2015) in his Con-
gressional Research Service report on China-U.S. Trade Issues mentions that the eco-
nomic relationship between these two countries has become increasingly complex
despite China being U.S.’s second largest trade partner. A major area of concern
expressed by U.S. policymakers is China’s relatively poor record of intellectual prop-
erty rights (IPR) enforcement. On the U.S. views regarding how to better address
commercial disputes with China, Morrison mentions of an aggressive stand in the form
of trade sanctions, along with other non-punitive initiatives like free trade agreement.
1
However, despite the use of tariffs and non-tariff barriers as threat instruments, the
incidence of IPR violation has increased in many developing countries. For example,
the Business Software Alliance (BSA) Global Software Survey (2013) reports that,
emerging economies are the major sources for the rise in global software piracy. The
commercial piracy rate in the Asia Pacific region increased from 60% in 2011 to 62%
in 2013.
2
Thus, unilateral trade barriers or sanctions seem to be an ineffective instrument for
restricting IPR violation in the developing countries. This is also partly evident from
the observation that stricter IPR protection policies in the developing countries are set
as precondition by the developed countries in negotiations on Free Trade
Agreements.
3
These observations thus raise two issues, which are the main focus of our paper.
First, whether imposition of import tariff on non-patented products from developing
* Acharyya: Department of Economics, Jadavpur University, Raja S.C. Mallik Road., Kolkata, 700032,
India. E-mail: rajat.acharyya@gmail.com. Banerjee: Department of Economics, Monash University,
Wellington Road, Clayton, VIC, 3800, Australia. Rajat Acharyya thanks Bill Ethier, Charles Van
Marrewjik, Roy Ruffin and Kalyan Sanyal for helpful comments and suggestions on an earlier draft. We
would like to thank two anonymous referees whose comments and suggestions have significantly contrib-
uted in improving the quality of the paper. The usual disclaimer applies.
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Review of International Economics, 25(2), 233–261, 2017
DOI:10.1111/roie.12263
countries, as an indirect punitive measure, induces them to strengthen their IPR
enforcement policy. Second, whether such a tariff can effectively reduce the incidence
of IPR violation in developing countries.
As explained in this paper, a strengthened IPR enforcement policy does not neces-
sarily mean an effective reduction of the incidence of IPR violation, or more specifi-
cally, the incidence of commercial piracy of a copyrighted good. Accordingly, both
these issues mentioned above, though are intertwined, need to be addressed sepa-
rately. On the other hand, our consideration of a tariff on import of a non-patented
good as an indirect punitive measure is more relevant than a tariff (or non-tariff bar-
rier) on import of a copyright-violated good because developing countries more often
use illegal appropriation of research output to compete with the patent/copyright
holder in their own markets rather than exporting it back to the developed country.
Thus, there is little or no scope for the use of trade barriers as direct punitive action to
strengthen IPR enforcement policy in the developing countries. Trade barriers on
imports of non-patented goods from developing countries as indirect punitive action
can still be relevant to the extent to which such policies inflict real income losses by
worsening the terms of trade for them.
There is a vast literature addressing the effect of IPR protection on innovation,
technology transfer, foreign direct investment, and licensing. However, this literature
does not address the effect of a country’s increased restrictive trade policy on the IPR
enforcement policies of her trading partner where copyright violation is prevalent.
4
The same issue is yet to be addressed in the literature on commercial and end-user
piracy, where the focus is on the effect of monitoring on piracy within a country.
5
Zigic
(2000) is the only exception, who shows that tariff can be effective in reducing illegal
appropriation in developing countries if the illegally appropriated product is exported
back to the developed country. In this case tariff prohibits the export of IPR violated
products and thus acts as a deterrent. Therefore, his analysis is not directly relevant in
the present context as we focus on tariff on import of non-patented goods as an indi-
rect punitive action for reasons mentioned above.
For the purpose, we construct a general equilibrium framework of a global economy
with only two countries: the South (or the developing country) and the North (or the
developed country). Two basic goods, garment and food, and a copyright-protected
product (software), are produced in this global economy by internationally immobile
labor and land. While both countries produce food, garment is produced and con-
sumed in the South and exported to North.
6
Software is innovated and produced only
in the North and is domestically consumed as well as exported to the South where
unauthorized copies of the copyrighted software are illegally sold thereby violating
IPR. However, such illegal appropriation of research output is not exported back to
the North and only sold in the domestic market in the South. Thus the copied software
is a non-traded good, unlike garment and the copyrighted software, all of which are
traded according to the assumed pattern of production specialization. The degree of
monitoring of such illicit activities measures the strength of South’s IPR protection.
South chooses the monitoring rate that maximizes her social welfare which is a
weighted average of the net utility derive d from the consumption of f ood, garment,
copyrighted software and copied software, and the positive benefit associated with the
expected net revenue from the fine collected from the detection of piracy. The benefit
captures the positive externalities from complying with IPR protection. The weight
captures South’s valuation of the relative importance of the benefit from adhering to
IPR laws.
234 Rajat Acharyya and Dyuti S. Banerjee
V
C2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT