Does foreign media entry discipline or provoke local media bias?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12099
Date01 December 2016
Published date01 December 2016
AuthorHon Foong Cheah
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12099
Does foreign media entry discipline or provoke local
media bias?
Hon Foong Cheah
This paper studies how the entry of an imperfectly informed foreign media outlet removes the
government’s roleas the sole provider of information, altering its repor ting tomaximize citizen
support. We find that while foreign media entry typically lowers local media bias, it can also
exacerbate bias in countries with an incompetent government. The resulting deterioration in
local media quality can outweigh the additional information from a foreign media of moderate
quality, leaving citizens worse off. When analyzing a government’s decision to suppress foreign
media, we find that suppression is most heavily used in countries with a moderately competent
government.
Key wor ds Government control of media, media bias, welfare implication
JEL classification D83, D82, D72
Accepted 17 February 2015
1 Introduction
Social scientists generally agree that press freedom promotes better governance1and is crucial in
maintaining a well-functioning democracy. In countries where the government controls the press,
the need for unbiased information drives citizens to seek alternative news sources. While the dis-
semination of subversive literature has existed since the birth of the printing press, todayprohibited
information is accessible on social media and blogs with the help of ingenious hackers circumvent-
ing the Internet firewall.2As communication technology continues to improve, the notion that a
government can control or manipulate all information outlets becomes more unrealistic.
There is a sense that the appearance of a new foreign source of information enables the public
to make better-informed choices. However, this simple story ignores the interaction between foreign
media and pre-existing sources of information through government-controlled media. This interac-
tion and the resulting overall effect on information and on citizens’welfare are the focus of this paper.
Wefind that the interaction effect can reinforce the basic story, or overturn it. Tomodel government
control of the media, we follow Gehlbach and Sonin (2009) who assume a program that promises
potential benefit to citizens who invest in it. This investment is a metaphor to capture in a simple
way a potential conflict of interest between government and individual citizens. A citizen’s decision
Zhejiang University of Science and Technology, Xihu District, Hangzhou, Zhejiang Province, China. Email:
honfcheah@gmail.com
1Representativeliterature includes Brunetti and Weder (2003) on media freedom and corruption, Ravallion (1997) on the
effect of the presence of an international news outlet on the incidence of famine, and Snyder and Str¨
omberg (2004) and
Str¨
omberg (2004) on the impact of the media on citizen responsiveness to political issues.
2See Parry (2008) on the role of mobile phones in spreading news on the North Koreanfood crisis.
International Journal of Economic Theory 12 (2016) 335–359 © IAET 335
International Journal of Economic Theory
Foreign media entry and local media bias Hon Foong Cheah
to invest represents any action that the government wants from individual citizens, to further its
ideological goals, to enhance its political power, or to seek collective support for certain economic
policies. Since these actions may be costly to individual citizens, through control of the media a gov-
ernment is tasked with persuading citizens to undertake its desired action by exaggerating the degree
to which the action is in their best interests. But citizens are aware of the government’s propensity to
exaggerate, and so discount its media reports accordingly.
While foreign media represent an additional information source for citizens to make better-
informed choices, we assume that the government cannot manipulate foreign media reports, and its
information is accessible to citizens at no additional cost. This departs from the assumption in some
parts of the literature of complete reliance on a single source of information (Gehlbach and Sonin
2009), and that all information outlets are susceptible to government manipulation (Besley and Prat
2006). Two additional restrictions are imposed on the nature of information available to citizens.
First, the foreign media, as “outsiders”, rely on less accurate information sourcescompared to those
available to government-controlled media, which indirectly reflectsthe government’s ability to stifle
the access of foreign media to relevant information sources.3Second, foreign media maximize their
advertising profit by maintaining a truth-telling editorial policy, ignoring the profit motive that
biases reporting to conform with its audience’s prior beliefs.4Both restrictions imply a government-
controlled media sector that is accurate but biased due to its propensity to exaggerate; and a foreign
media sector that is unbiased but potentially inaccurate. Therefore citizens treat both sources of
information as complements,5and any changes in the government’s propensity to exaggerate alters
the quality of information available to citizens and affect their investment decisions.
The interaction between the government and the general public relates to Kamenica and
Gentzkow (2011), where a government-controlled media sector can commit to a specific editorial
policy, allowing the general public to decide their investment strategy based on media reports. The
government need not worry about the public’s interpretationof its action, eliminating the possibilit y
of a babbling equilibrium, an equilibrium in which only uninformative information is transmit-
ted between a sender and a receiver. On the subject of media suppression, Besley and Prat (2006)
highlight that the existence of a greater number of independent news outlets raises the likelihood
of press freedom because a government is required to pay each outlet the sum they would earn in a
monopoly news market. But our focus here is different because we assume that independent news
reports cannot be silenced. Gehlbach and Sonin (2009) highlight two different methods of media
control: bribery and government takeover,and show that increasing the importance of a news outlet’s
advertising revenue increases a government’s incentive to take over domestic news outlets.6While
our framework closely resembles that of Gehlbach and Sonin (2009), our main focus in on the influ-
3Toinfluencenews repor ting, governmentrewards with inside scoops those outlets that report favorably on the government,
while preventingaccess to outlets that provide accurate information to maximize advertising revenue from their audience.
See Besley and Prat (2006, section II.D) for a discussion.
4This is also known as ‘demand-side bias’. Representative papers include Gentzkowand Shapiro (2006), which examines
the reputation incentiveof inaccurate media outlets to bias their reporting to conform with their consumers’ prior beliefs.
Mullainathan and Shleifer (2005) discuss media outlets’ incentiveto bias reporting in order to segment consumers with
different prior beliefs. Groseclose and Mylio (2005) and Gentzkow and Shapiro (2006) demonstrate a relation between
media bias and audiences’ political beliefs in the UnitedStates newspaper market.
5During the Cold War,Russians tuned to foreign broadcasts such as Voiceof America and Radio Liberty for “infor mation
sources that they may not always believe, but that was alwaysavailable as a check on the generally accepted unreliability
of their own broadcast and newspapers” (Shanor 1985).
6In a different institutional setting, Gentzkowet al. (2006) attribute the increase in informativeness in US newspapers from
1870 to 1920 to increasing the importance of advertising revenue.
336 International Journal of Economic Theory 12 (2016) 335–359 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT