Do demographics affect monetary policy transmission in Canada?

AuthorSteve Ambler,Jeremy Kronick
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1691
Published date01 April 2019
Date01 April 2019
Received: 29 March 2018 Revised: 3 August 2018 Accepted: 9 September 2018
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1691
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Do demographics affect monetary policy transmission in
Canada?
Jeremy Kronick1Steve Ambler2
1C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto,ON,
Canada
2ESG UQAM, C.D. Howe Institute,
Toronto,ON, Canada
Correspondence
Steve Ambler, ESG UQAM,C.D. Howe
Institute, Toronto,ON, Canada.
Email: ambler.steven@uqam.ca
JEL Classification: E52; E58
Handling Editor: Taylor Mark
Abstract
Using a panel of macroeconomic data for Canada and its 10 provinces, we
estimate the dynamic effects of monetary policy shocks from the mid-1980s
until the present. We then relate the change in the impact of these shocks to
macroeconomic factors including demographics, specifically changes in the old
age dependency ratio. We find that the inflation-targeting regime has had an
ambiguous effect on the impact of monetary policy shocks in Canada. On the
other hand, changing demographics have unambiguously reduced the impact of
monetary policy shocks. This can help to explain tepid inflation since the finan-
cial crisis and could eventually undermine the effectiveness of Canada's inflation
targeting regime.
KEYWORDS
Canada, credit channel, demographic change, inflation targeting, monetary policy
1INTRODUCTION
A large number of countries have adopted inflation tar-
geting (IT) since the early 1990s. Overall, the experiment
with IT has been very successful,1at least until the onset of
the financial crisis and the Great Recession in 2007–2008.
However,since the crisis, inflation has been systematically
below target in many countries in spite of rock-bottom
interest rates and different forms of unconventional mon-
etary policy such as quantitative easing. Canada has not
been spared this phenomenon. Since 2010, inflation in
Canada has averaged 1.6%, well under the 2% target. This
paper asks what role demographic changes, in particu-
lar an aging population, have had on the transmission of
monetary policy. Although demographics is an issue for
both IT and non-IT regimes, we focus on the former as a
result of the missing inflation post-crisis that has plagued
countries whose central banks have an explicit inflation
mandate.2Nevertheless, any country with a central bank
that uses a short-term interest rate as its primary mone-
tary policy instrument would also face the same effects of
demographic change on monetary policy transmission.
The economic context of IT and the transmission of
monetary policy has changed gradually over the last
30 years. Most notably,real and nominal interest rates have
decreased gradually (with a sudden decrease at the onset of
the financial crisis and the Great Recession), and long-run
neutral interest rates are now lower than they were. This
has important consequences for central banks, because
the probability that policy rates will be pushed by nega-
tive shocks to their effective lower bound has increased.
This leaves less room for reducing policy rates in order to
stimulate demand.3
One of the main influences on long-term real inter-
est rates is demographic change. Population growth has
been slowing in developed economies, putting a brake on
the rate of increase of the size of active populations, and
increasing the proportion of older people. As the propor-
tion of older people increases, the long-term equilibrium
real interest rate falls as demand for capital decreases.4
Furthermore, changing demographics in principle can
affect the impact of monetary policy because changes in
interest rateshave different effects on different age cohorts:
this means that the population age pyramid matters for the
Int J Fin Econ. 2019;24:787–811. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe ©2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 787
788 KRONICK AND AMBLER
response to changes in central banks' policy rates. In turn,
this occurs mainly because individuals' and households'
wealth over the life cycle is not constant.
In Canada, the median age in 1971 was 26.2, and has
steadily risen,5reaching 40.6 in 2017. Additionally, for
the first time, there are now more Canadians over 65
than under 15 (Robson, 2017). Offsetting some of this
increase in median age is the fact that life expectancy has
increased,which hasled some todelayretirement.6Rega rd-
less, Canada's aging population, and the resulting fall in
demand for capital, has pushed down the neutral rate of
interest over the past 10 years and now sits, according to
the Bank of Canada, somewhere between 2.5% and 3.5%.
Additionally, the relationship between the level of eco-
nomic activity and inflation has weakened gradually over
the last 30 years. This has often been referred to as a flat-
tening of the Phillips curve and is true in most industri-
alized economies. The implications of this phenomenon
are mixed. On the one hand, if long-run inflation expecta-
tions are tied to the inflation target, imbalances between
demand and supply are less likely to move inflation from
target. On the other hand, it can also mean that central
banks, in order to alter inflation rates, must affect aggre-
gate demand and output even more than before.7What all
this means is that the Bank of Canada is starting from a
lower neutral interest rate with less room to decrease the
overnight rate, in an environmentwhere they may actually
need to stimulate more than before in order to generate any
desired change in prices.
The goal of this paper is to examine the link between
demographics and the impact of Canadian monetary pol-
icy shocks over time. We use a two-stage estimation pro-
cedure similar to that of Imam (2015). In the first stage,
we use a time-varying coefficient Bayesian vector autore-
gression (TVC-BVAR), where we take advantage of a new
data set from Champagne and Sekkel (2017) for a more
appropriate identification of Canadian monetary policy
shocks. Indeed, this new shock series helps to alleviate
the price puzzle that arises from standard structural vec-
tor autoregression (SVAR) set-ups. We use this TVC-BVAR
to estimate the impact of monetary policy shocks over
the 1985:Q2 to 2015:Q4 period. We measure the impact
of monetary policy shocks by both the maximum and the
cumulative increase or decrease in inflation and unem-
ployment in response to a shock of the same size.
In the second stage, we exploit a database of macroeco-
nomic variables for a cross section of Canadian provinces
and use dynamic panel estimation to evaluate the link
between demographics and the impact of Canadian mon-
etary policy. By exploiting these provincial data sets, we
provide a more accurate assessment of the impact of mon-
etary policy in Canada, in comparison with Imam (2015)
who focuses on a cross section of different countries.
Our primary finding is that demographic change has
reduced the impact of monetary policy shocks. Since mon-
etary policy has been expansionary for the bulk of the
period under analysis, the implication is that lower inter-
est rates have not, all other things being equal, led to
as much increased borrowing and demand, and in turn,
the impact on inflation and the real economy has been
weaker than it would have been in the absence of demo-
graphic change.8We find that the interest rate and credit
channels are important transmission mechanisms high-
lighting the fact that an aging population tends to have
lower debt levels—as the need for significant borrowing
decreases—and are therefore less sensitive to movements
in interest rates. Our conclusion is that demographic
change is a plausible partial explanation for why inflation
has been unable to reach higher levels post-crisis, despite
considerable monetary policy stimulus.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In the
following section, we review different possible channels
through which monetary policy operates, not all of which
imply the same sign for the relationship between the old
age dependency ratio and its impact. In Section 3, we
summarize our econometric methodology and results. In
Section 4, we do some sensitivity analysis, including dis-
cussing the results with different lag timing. Section 5
concludes.
2DIFFERENT CHANNELS FOR
MONETARY POLICY
TRANSMISSION
In this section, we look at the three primary transmission
channels discussed by Imam (2015): the interest rate chan-
nel, the credit channel, and the wealth channel. One other
potential transmission channel for a small open economy
is the exchange rate channel.9Our choice to not explic-
itly investigate this channel is due to two factors. First, the
effect of the channel is ambiguous. Aging populations tend
to be characterized by a decline in savingsbut also a decline
in investments. Similarly, public savings and investments
fall with aging populations due to declining revenues and
higher expenditures. It is this combination of private and
public savings or investments that define the net effect on
the current account and therefore on the exchange rate.
Because it is not clear ex ante which of the decline in sav-
ings and investment outweighs the other, the effect of the
channel is ambiguous.
The second reason is that the exchange rate itself, as we
show in the next section, is directly accounted for in the
Bank of Canada's reaction function in the development
of the monetary policy shock series. Therefore, the exoge-
nous component of the monetary policy shock, and the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT