Discrimination, human capital, and life expectancy in a model of economic development

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12155
AuthorNorman Sedgley,Bruce Elmslie
Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
Discrimination, human capital, and life expectancy
in a model of economic development
Norman Sedgley
and Bruce Elmslie
y
Evidence suggests that race- and gender-based discrimination are prevalent. If discrimination
misallocates resources then it is likely to generate social costs. This paper provides a general
equilibrium model of the impacts of discrimination. We analyze effects of labor market
discrimination in a model where agents make human capital decisions based on comparing the
marginal benefits and marginal costs of additional human capital accumulation. Life expectancy
is a consideration in making human capital decisions, and is allowed to be endogenous. We find
that the impact of discrimination on equilibrium depends on the nature of any skills bias in
discrimination.
Key words discrimination, economic development, life expectancy, human capital, welfare
economics
JEL classification E10, J71, D61
Accepted 5 May 2017
1 Introduction
Most economists agree that labor market discrimination, based on race or gender, is a prevalent
phenomenon. If discrimination misallocates resources then it is likely to have significant social costs.
Macroeconomic models of these costs are rare, but the studies that exist suggest that they may be
large. This paper attempts to fill a gap in the literature by providing a macroeconomic model of
the general equilibrium impacts of discrimination on economic development. We analyze the
general equilibrium effects of labor market discrimination in a model where agents make human
capital decisions based on comparing the marginal benefits and marginal costs of additional human
capital accumulation. The cost of additional schooling is modeled as the value of an agent’s time
measured in terms of forgone earnings. Life expectancy is a consideration in making human capital
decisions. We allow life expectancy to be endogenous and dependent on the level of skills or human
capital accumulated. A major result of the model is that the impact of discrimination on
macroeconomic equilibrium depends on the nature of any skills bias in discrimination.
Economists have highlighted many fundamental reasons for differences across countries in the
degree of economic development. These reasons include factors as diverse as international trade
openness, multinational enterprise investment, equipment investment, the distribution of income,
inflation, and socialism (Easterly 1993; Fischer 1993). Perhaps the variable that has received the most
attention is educational attainment and training. In the case of lagging countries, Verspagen (1991)
Department of Economics, Sellinger School of Business and Management, Loyola University in Maryland, Baltimore,
Maryland, USA. Email: nsedgley@loyola.edu
y
Department of Economics, University of New Hampshire, McConnell Hall, Durham, New Hampshire, USA.
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12155
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 211–231 ©IAET 211
International Journal of Economic Theory
models what he calls a country’s ‘‘intrinsic learning capability’’ as a determinant of knowledge
spillovers from advanced countries, while Hikino and Amsden (1994) include educational
attainment (especially of civil servants) as a key determinant of convergence. Moreover, Barro (1991,
1997), Levine and Renelt (1992), Mankiw et al. (1992), and Jones (2002) find educational attainment
to be an important determinant of growth for both leading and lagging countries. Hanushek and
Kinko (2000) use international math and science scores as an output measure of educational
attainment. They find a strong correlation between test scores and growth rates. Most empirical
research on growth finds that human capital accumulation is an important key to economic growth
and/or levels of per-capita gross domestic product.
This paper contributes to the discussion by modeling the role labor market discrimination plays
in determining capital to labor ratios and output per capita. It is important to recognize that there are
likely to be cumulative effects of discrimination on macroeconomic performance, with
consequences for the whole of the population. The research to date, however, has not recognized
the potential importance of the market distortions created by discrimination, endogenous human
capital choices and life expectancy that are highlighted in the current work.
There are three questions in the literature that directly impact the contribution of this paper.
First, what is the extent of discrimination in labor markets? Second, given that evidence of
discrimination can be found, what is the nature of the bias in discrimination with regard to skills?
Finally, what are the impacts from discrimination and the nature of its skills bias on macroeconomic
equilibrium outcomes such as growth rates and/or per-capita income?
We begin with the extent of discrimination which evidence suggests is a prevalent phenomenon.
A majority of work on discrimination uses data from the US labor market, though the results are
representative of a large cross-section of nations with significant minority populations and ethnic
diversity. Studies based on the decomposition described by Oaxacca (1973) document robust
evidence of gender- and race-based discrimination (Cotton 1988; Neumark 1988; Boston 1990; Main
1991; Gyimah-Brempong et al. 1992; Weinberger 1998; Coleman 2003; Bertrand and Mullainathan
2004; Jarrell and Stanley 2004; Carneiro et al. 2005). These papers suggest that race and gender wage
gaps have ranged between 30% and 60%, and 35–70% of the gap can be explained by factors other
than labor market discrimination, such as individual human capital choices.
Given that evidence of significant wage discrimination exists for various groups, is the
discrimination biased by skill level? Couch and Daly (2002) report that the black wage gap fell from
50% in 1967 to 30% by the late 1980s. The gap then fell, on average, by about 1% per year throughout
the 1990s, leaving approximately a 20% wage gap in 2000. Also of significance is their estimate that
the wage gap does not decrease at the same rate across skill levels. They report the most rapid
convergence for young workers with little work experience. This implies that relative levels of
discrimination for blacks in the USA are increasing with education. This seems reasonable since
minimum-wage laws create an artificial wage floor only for low-skill workers. Many other papers
document a potential skills bias in wage gaps (Cotton 1988; Duncan 1992; Gyimah-Brempong et al.
1992; Rogers and Armentrout 1996; Garc
ıa et al. 2001; Bertrand and Mullainathan 2004;
Munasinghe et al. 2008). Generally the evidence suggests that women and minorities gain lower
marginal wages from additional education, experience, and on-the-job training.
Much of the literature finds evidence that discrimination and its skills bias are measurable aspects
of real labor markets. As people respond to these differential returns to human capital accumulation,
discrimination might lead to a misallocation of resources. If resources are not efficiently allocated
significant costs to society can arise. Studies that investigate the potential impacts of discrimination
on an aggregate level are surprisingly rare.
Discrimination, human capital, and life expectancy Norman Sedgley and Bruce Elmslie
212 International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 211–232 ©IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT