Decision making with intuitionistic linguistic preference relations

AuthorQingxian An,Fanyong Meng,Jie Tang,Xiaohong Chen
Date01 September 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/itor.12383
Published date01 September 2019
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 2004–2031
DOI: 10.1111/itor.12383
INTERNATIONAL
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
RESEARCH
Decision making with intuitionistic linguistic preference
relations
Fanyong Menga,b, Jie Tanga, Qingxian Anaand Xiaohong Chena,c
aSchool of Business, Central South University, Changsha 410083, China
bCollaborative Innovation Center on Forecast and Nanjing University of Information Science and Technology,
Nanjing 210044, China
cSchool of Accounting, Hunan University of Commerce,Changsha 410205, China
E-mail: mengfanyongtjie@163.com [Meng]; tjie411@126.com [Tang]; anqingxian@csu.edu.cn [An];
cxh@csu.edu.cn [Chen]
Received 17 December 2015; receivedin revised form 21 October 2016; accepted 24 November 2016
Abstract
To address the preferred and nonpreferred degrees of linguistic variables, this paper introduces intuitionis-
tic linguistic preference relations (ILPRs) that apply intuitionistic linguistic variables (ILVs) to denote the
decision makers’ preferences. To judge the consistency of ILPRs, a consistent concept is introduced, and a
consistency index is defined. When ILPRs are unacceptably inconsistent, a method to improve the consis-
tency is introduced. Then, an approach to rank ILVs is introduced.In some situations where ILPRs might be
incomplete, the consistency-based linear programming model is constructed to evaluate the missing values.
Considering group decision making, a group consensus index is defined, and its several desirable properties
are discussed. Meanwhile, an acceptability-based consistency and consensus approach is developed, and the
associated example is offered to show the efficiency of the proposed procedure.
Keywords: intuitionistic linguistic preference relation; consistency index; group consensus index; aggregation operator;
programming model
1. Introduction
A decision-making problem usually requires at least one decision maker to evaluate and rank a
heterogeneous set of objects. The analytic hierarchy process (AHP) (see Saaty, 1980) is an efficient
and powerful tool to cope with decision-making problems that need the decision maker to compare
each pair of objects according to every criterion and give their judgments. Since Saaty (1980)
first introduced the AHP to us, it has been largely developed (see Orlovsky, 1978; Buckley, 1985;
Choudhury et al., 2006; Xu, 2006, 2007; Srdjevic, 2007; Xia et al., 2013). According to the preference
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA02148,
USA.
F. Meng et al. / Intl. Trans.in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 2004–2031 2005
value, the preferencerelation can be classified into two types. One type is the quantitative preference
relation (see Orlovsky, 1978; Buckley, 1985; Singh et al., 1989; Xu, 2007, Xu and Yager, 2009; Xia
et al., 2013; Meng et al., 2016c), and the other type is the qualitativepreference relation (see Xu, 2006;
Tapia-Garc´
ıa et al., 2012; Zhang et al., 2012; Xia et al., 2014; Meng et al., 2016a, 2016b). Because
reciprocal preference relations (see Saaty, 1980) and fuzzy preference relations (see Orlovsky, 1978)
need the decision maker to offer his/her exact preference degree or intensity of one object over
another, this might be difficult or even impossible in some situations. Thus, researchers defined
several families of extended preference relations to denote the decision makers’ vague and uncertain
judgments (see Buckley, 1985; Xu, 2007; Xu and Yager, 2009; Tapia-Garc´
ıa et al., 2012; Wu and
Chiclana, 2014; Das and Guha, 2015; Das et al., 2016; Meng and Chen, 2016).
All above-mentioned preference relations need the decision maker to offer the quantitative judg-
ments. However, in some practical situations, the problems might be too complex or ill-defined to
use quantitative preferences. To cope with this issue, linguistic variables (see Zadeh, 1975) are a good
choice, as they clearly addressthe decision makers’ qualitative judgments. For instance, Herreraand
Mart´
ınez (2000) introduced a simple and novel linguistic representation model called the 2-tuple
linguistic representation model that consists of a pair of values: a linguistic term and a symbolic
translation value in [0.5, 0.5). Dong et al. (2008) proved that the extended linguistic aggrega-
tion (ELA) operator (see Xu, 2004) is equivalent to the associated 2-tuple linguistic aggregation
operator (Zhang et al., 2004). This means that there is no information loss by using the ELA oper-
ator to aggregate linguistic variables. Dong and Zhang (2014), Dong and Herrera-Viedma (2015),
and Dong et al. (2010) researched several methods for decision making with linguistic preference
relations.
Although linguistic preference relations are a powerful tool to express the decision makers’
qualitative preferences, they are based on the assumption that the preferred degree of one object
over another for a linguistic term is 1. However, as Xu (2007) noted, in some real-life situations
the decision maker might be not so confident for his/her preferences for objects because of various
reasons, such as imprecise or insufficientlevel of knowledge of the problem and the inter complexity
of objects. In such cases, it might be more suitable to express his/her preferences for objects with
a certain degree. To address these situations, intuitionistic linguistic variables (ILVs; see Wang and
Li, 2009) might be a good choice, which are expressedby a linguistic ter m, membership degree, and
nonmembership degree. In this paper, we pay our attention to decision making with intuitionistic
linguistic preference relations (ILPRs). To do this, the remainder of this paper is organized as
follows.
In Section 2, some basic and relative concepts are briefly reviewed. In Section 3, the concepts
of ILPRs and consistent ILPRs are introduced. Then, a consistency index (CI) is presented, and a
method to improvethe consistency is introduced. After that, the extended intuitionistic linguistic or-
dered weighted averaging (EILOWA)operator is defined. When the weights of the ordered positions
are not known, a model for determining the optimal symmetric weighting vector is constructed.
In Section 4, considering incomplete ILPRs, a consistency-based linear programming model is
constructed. In Section 5, a group consensus index (GCOI) is defined to measure the consensus of
ILPRs. When the consensus of individual ILPRs is unacceptable, an adjusted method to improve
the group consensus is presented. Then, an approach to group decision making with ILPRs is
developed. Concluding comments are given in the last section.
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation of OperationalResearch Societies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT