Data sharing agreements in vertically differentiated two‐sided markets

AuthorJuan‐Manuel Sánchez‐Cartas,Gonzalo León
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12192
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
Data sharing agreements in vertically differentiated
two-sided markets
Juan-Manuel S
anchez-Cartas
and Gonzalo Le
on
We study the impact of data sharing agreements between two platforms with vertically
differentiated consumers. We assume several utility functions to address the impact of those
agreements under different market configurations. The results show that the follower always
wants to share its network with the leader, while the leader has no incentive to share its network.
We also prove that vertical two-sided markets are quite prone to monopolies. Lastly, we show
that regimes in which the leader shares its network are worse than not sharing at all.
Key words two-sided market, data sharing, vertical differentiation, compatibility
JEL classification D43, K21 L11, L13, L15
Accepted 27 March 2018
1 Introduction
We study the effects of data sharing agreements and expectations in vertically differentiated
two-sided markets and their implications on price competition. Many real-life markets operate with
these features, indeed many digital markets follow this basic description. For example, apps such as
Google Fit and Garmin Connect can be described with these models. Those apps are platforms in
which users can follow their lifestyle, and developers can use users’ data to create new apps. So both
users and developers value the presence of the others on the platform. But other markets can also be
described, such as wearables and fitness trackers. In this case, some users may value the quality of the
device but may not care about the presence of advertisers/developers on the other side of the market.
However, other users such as runners and athletes may compete with each other, and in that sense
they value the presence of other athletes (direct network effect).
These examples share three features. First, all of them are prone to generating data sharing
agreements. For example, in the case of fitness platforms such as Endomondo and MyFitnessPal,
users can import/export their data from one platform to another but only use one of them.
1
In other
words, they singlehome, but they ‘‘are’’ on two platforms. From the developers’ point of view,
the Endomondo database consists not only of Endomondo users but also of some MyFitnessPal
users. The same is true in the fitness tracker market. For example, Fitbit and Withings have data
Centre for Technology Innovation (CAIT), Madrid Polytechnic University, Montegancedo Campus, Pozuelo de Alarc
on,
Spain. Email: juanmanuel.sanchez@upm.es
This work has been supported by Project H2020 FI-WARE, and especially by the Joint Research Unit between the
Universidad Polit
ecnica de Madrid (UPM) and Telef
onica R&D. We also thank the anonymous reviewer for valuable
comments.
1
https://goo.gl/V4K9S5
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12192
International Journal of Economic Theory xxx (2018) 1–22 ©IAET 1
International Journal of Economic Theory
International Journal of Economic Theory 16 (2020) 260–281 © IAET
260
sharing agreements that allow them to synchronize their devices with competitors’ platforms, which
means that they have larger databases to sell to advertisers or developers.
2
A second interesting fe ature is that not all users val ue the presence of other us ers (or the
quality of the product) in t he same way. At a given price, so me users put more value on the
presence of other users (o r the quality). Not all Ga rmin users value the pos sibility of getting in
touch with other users i n the same way, not all Goog le Fit users compete with other users i n
the same way, and not all Fitb it users value the techn ology of the device they are wearing in the
same way.
A third feature is that all of the aforementioned examples are digital markets.
We consider three different cases. The first is related to Gabszewicz and Wauthy (2004), which is
adopted as the framework for comparing. In the second we assume agents’ heterogeneity comes
from exogenous features (quality). In the third we assume heterogeneity comes from direct network
effects. In this last case we assume not only responsive expectations (or beliefs) but also passive
expectations.
We compare the three different scenarios with and without data sharing agreements. We show
that platforms’ profits are higher when the follower platform shares its data with the leader relative
to the case where there is no data sharing. In contrast, the case in which the leader shares its data
with the follower leads to a Bertrand equilibrium. As a matter of fact, from the leader’s point of view,
it is not profitable to share its data because it reduces the differentiation. We also find that multiple
equilibria are common to all frameworks. For instance, we find the coexistence of an asymmetric
interior equilibrium with the dominant firm equilibrium in which a company monopolizes the
market in a two-sided market with direct network effects, and in a market with exogenous quality
levels (when those quality levels are low and similar). Finally, this work provides an interesting
contrast with Hagiu and Halaburda’s (2014) results. In our work, platforms with more market power
prefer responsive users.
2 Literature review
Data sharing agreements are not a new concept.
3
However, the concept has new implications in the
digital economy. These new implications are mainly related to compatibility. As a matter of fact, data
sharing agreements can be considered as a kind of compatibility because they allow companies to
‘‘access’’ to the network of other companies.
Compatibility has a long tradition in the industrial organization literature, and it is a broader
concept than data sharing. In that sense, it is useful to analyze that literature to know how to address
the data sharing phenomenon.
We can identify two ways of addressing compatibility: one is the classical way based on one-sided
models, such as Katz and Shapiro (1985), Farrell and Saloner (1985, 1986), and Matutes and
Regibeau (1988), among others. These works have established the lines along which compatibility is
addressed.
However, as Wright (2004) points out, conventional knowledge from one-sided markets may
lead to mistakes in two-sided markets. In that sense, conclusions from the one-sided literature may
not be robust in two-sided markets. This suggests that policy-makers have to be careful not to base
2
https://goo.gl/mtRnZu or https://goo.gl/FMxKHT
3
We define a data sharing agreement as a contract by which platforms or companies allowother companies to access to
specific customer data for example, free access to the information about the lifestyle of users.
Data sharing agreements Juan-Manuel S
anchez-Cartas and Gonzalo Le
on
2International Journal of Economic Theory xxx (2018) 1–22 ©IAET
International Journal of Economic Theory 16 (2020) 260–281 © IAET 261

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT