Cournot, Bertrand or Chamberlin: Toward a reconciliation

AuthorJacques‐François Thisse,Evgeny V. Zhelobodko,Mathieu Parenti,Alexander V. Sidorov
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12116
Published date01 March 2017
Date01 March 2017
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12116
Cournot, Bertrand or Chamberlin: Toward a reconciliation
Mathieu Parenti,Alexander V. Sidorov,Jacques-Franc¸ois Thisseand Evgeny V. Zhelobodko§
This paper compares the market equilibria in a differentiated industry under Cournot, Bertrand,
and monopolistic competition. This is accomplished in a one-sector economywhere consumers
are endowed with separable preferences. When firms are free to enter the market, monopolisti-
cally competitive firms charge lower prices than oligopolistic firms, while the mass of varieties
provided by the market is smaller under the former than the latter. Ifthe economy is sufficiently
large, Cournot, Bertrand and Chamberlin solutions converge toward the same market outcome,
which may be a competitive or a monopolistically competitive equilibrium, depending on the
nature of preferences.
Key wor ds Cournot competition, Bertrand competition, monopolistic competition, free entry
JEL classification D43, D41, F12, L13
Accepted 9 January 2016
1 Introduction
The theory of imperfect competition is dominated by two approaches that seem to clash with each
other. Whereasindustrial organization stresses the importance of strategic interactions among firms,
the model of imperfect competition used in economic fields such as trade, economic geography and
growth is the CES model of monopolistic competition developed by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977).In
this model, any form of interaction among firms is absent. In addition, in oligopolistic markets,
price (Bertrand) and quantity (Cournot) competition deliver market solutions that typically differ,
making it hard to formulate robust predictions. The purpose of this paper is to contribute to this
debate by providing a comparison of these three types of competition. This is accomplished in an
economy involving one sector and a population of consumers endowed with separable preferences
and a finite number of labor units. Although we recognize that additive preferences are restrictive,
they are widely used in the literature and suffice to shed new light on old questions. Note also that
the budget constraint implies that firms do not behave like monopolists.
According to the folk theorem of competitive markets, perfect competition almost holds when
firms are small relative to the size of the market. In the same spirit, there was a live debate in the
1930s between, on one side, Chamberlin (1933) and, on the other, Robinson (1934) and Kaldor
ECARES, Universit´
e Libre de Bruxelles (Belgium) and CEPR. Email: mparenti@ulb.ac.be
Novosibirsk State University, Sobolev Institute for Mathematics and NRU-Higher School of Economics(Russia).
CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium), NRU-Higher School of Economics (Russia)and CEPR.
§Novosibirsk State Universityand NRU-Higher School of Economics (Russia).
We thank an anonymousreferee, Alexander Osharin and Philip Ushchev for comments and suggestions. This study has
been funded by the Russian AcademicExcellence Project 5-100, and Russian Foundation for Basic Research 15-06-05666.
International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 29–45 © IAET 29
International Journal of Economic Theory
Cournot, Bertrand or Chamberlin Mathieu Parenti et al.
(1935) about the relevance of monopolistic competition as a possible market structure. Robinson
and Kaldor maintained against Chamberlin that perfect competition must emerge when the number
of firms becomes arbitrarily large relative to market size. No clear answer came out of this debate
because these authors lacked the analytical tools to study the convergence issue. Our paper shows
that the answer depends on the nature of preferences.
It was not until 1980 that Novshekwas able to tackle the convergence issue rigorously for Cournot
games in which firms produce a homogeneous good and face U-shaped average costs. Inthe spir it of
methods used in general equilibrium theory, Novshek (1980) chose to make firms small relative to
the market by replicating the demand side. When the number of replications is sufficiently large, the
equilibrium is nearly competitive. As for Bertrand differentiated oligopoly,Novshek and Chowdhury
(2003) showed that the convergence of the Bertrand equilibria toward the perfectly competitive
equilibrium may not take place, even under strong assumptions on technologies.
Our main findings are as follows. Wefirst show that a Cournot differentiated oligopoly generates
a higher markup than a Bertrand differentiated oligopoly when the number of firms is exogenously
given. This is in accordance with the folk wisdom of industrial organization according to which
Cournot competition is softer than Bertrand competition. Second, as the number of competitors
becomes arbitrarily large, both types of competition deliver the same equilibrium outcome. Whether
the limit of Cournot and Bertrand competition is perfectly competitive or monopolistically compet-
itive depends on consumers’ attitude toward product differentiation. Using the concept of relative
love for variety,which measures the intensity of the preference for variety, we show that each firm op-
erating in a large economy retains enough market power toenjoy a positive markup when the relative
love for variety remains bounded away from zero at arbitrarily low consumption levels. In contrast,
when the relative love for variety vanishes at zero, consumers cease tovalue product differentiation.
A growing number of firms thus leads to the perfectly competitive outcome. In sum, the market
structure that emerges as the limit of oligopolistic competition depends on the nature of preferences. Fi-
nally,when fir ms arefree to enter the market, monopolistically competitive firms are more aggressive
than oligopolistic firms in that these firms charge lower prices, while the mass of varieties provided
by the market is smaller under oligopolistic competition than under monopolistic competition. If
the economy is sufficiently large, Cournot, Bertrand and Chamberlin solutions converge toward the
same market outcome, which need not be a competitive equilibrium.
2 The model
2.1 Firms and consumers
There is one sector supplying a horizontally differentiated good, one production factor (labor),
and a mass Lof identical consumers. Each consumer supplies one unit of labor and owns 1/L of
firms’ profits. The labor market is perfectly competitive and labor is chosen as the numeraire. The
differentiated good is made available in the form of a finite number n2 of varieties. Each variety
is produced by a single firm and each firm produces a single variety. To operate, every firm needs a
fixed requirement f0 and a marginal requirement c>0 of labor. Since wage is normalized to 1,
the cost of producing qiunits of variety i=1,...,nis equal to f+cqi.
Consumers share the same additive preferences given by
U(x)=
n
i=1
u(xi),(1)
30 International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 29–45 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT