Connectivity in East Asia

Date01 July 2016
Published date01 July 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12132
AuthorDouglas H. Brooks
Connectivity in East Asia
Douglas H. BROOKS
The AustralianAPEC Study Centre
As Asian economies have become more connected through physical andinstitutional infrastructure,
the regions trade has grown and changed. Intraregional trade has increased its share, in large part
through the expansion of trade in intermediates in connection with development of global value
chains. At the sametime, as part of the same process and as part of the structural transformation that
underlies most economic development, the share of services in Asias trade has risen. Policies that
support the development of regional infrastructure and the flow of goods and services, as well as
factors of production, can increase the benefits from connectivity. Meanwhile, regional cooperation
has a key role to play in mitigating negative impacts that may arise from the vulnerabilities that
accompany greater connectivity.
Key words: connectivity,global value chains, infrastructure, structural transformation, trade
JEL codes: F15, F13, O14, O19
1. Introduction
Asias re-emergence as an economic powerhouse owes much to the expansion of its
international trade and investment, and particularly to its intraregional flows of traded
goods (raw materials, intermediate goods, and final goods) and services, capital,
information,and, to a lesser extent,labor. Asias increased connectivity and integration have
been fostered by theconnections of supporting infrastructure, both hard (physical) and soft
(institutional), greater credit availability, and efficient logistics services. This connectivity
may be defined as the linking of geographical locations, economic activities, and
institutions, to enable flows of goods, services, finance, technology, ideas, and people.
In the Ricardian model of international trade with at least some immobile factors of
production, comparative advantagedetermines the gains from trade throughspecialization
in production and the movement of final goods. In todays globalized economy,
governments struggle to monitor and control flows of financial capital, to develop mutual
recognition agreements for the movement of skilled labor (and despair of controlling the
illegal migration of unskilled labor), and encourage investment in other countriesnatural
resources. Flows of traded final goods frequently derive from flows of intermediate goods,
and are now as likely to engender trade in services as vice-versa. Flows of information
The author gratefully acknowledges helpful comments by Ken Waller, David Green, and the
participants of the Twenty Second Asian Economic Policy Review Conference, Tokyo, 10 October
2015. Bekzod Abdullaev providedvaluable research assistance.
Correspondence: Douglas H. Brooks, The Australian APEC Study Centre, RMIT University, Room 26,
Level 6, Building 80, 445 Swanston Street, Melbourne, Vic. 3000, Australia. Email: doug@apec.org.au
doi: 10.1111/aepr.12132 Asian EconomicPolicy Review (2016) 11, 176194
176 ©2016Japan Center for EconomicResearch
bs_bs_banner
and other intangibles incite andenhance flows of goods, services,and factors of production,
as well as logistics to facilitatethe flows. Internationally, these developments have beenmost
obvious, and probably most beneficial, in East Asia.
Changes in technology and policy have influenced intrafirm transaction costs and
therefore production processes, allowing fragmentation, outsourcing, and offshoring.
Where previous production and delivery systems have become unbundleddue to
technological developments, as in the energy sector, they have led to rethinking the roles
of public and privatesectors. Where they have foundmore efficient modes of transportation
and distribution(such as the advent of standardizedshipping containers, or applyingdigital
technology to reform customs procedures) they have lowered trade costs and sparked a
proliferation of outsourcing for parts, components, and services.
1
As recently as the 1960s, the prevailing paradigm of economic policy in developing
countries supported import substitution and infant industry protection. The newly
industrialized economies (NIEs) of Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan had
reasons
2
to challenge that orthodoxy, rapidly increased their trade and for the most part
welcomed foreign direct investment. Technological developments, such as the
introduction of container transport, and financial deepening and exchange rate
realignments following the end of the Bretton Woods currency system and the mid-
1980s Plaza Accord facilitated the process. As their growth accelerated, their example
helped persuade other economies, particularly in East Asia, to adopt similar paths. While
this process came to be known as export-led development,imports of capital goods (in
large part to support production of exports) played an even more critical role most
countries in the region ran persistent trade deficits from the mid-1970s until the
19971998 Asian Financial Crisis.
The tradability of many manufactured goods produced during East Asias
industrialization meant that economies could expand rapidly without turning terms
of trade against themselves, while specializing in a relatively narrow range of goods
allowed a more manageable policy reform process. As global value chains took hold
through the region they facilitated entry to manufacturing but diminished returns
from it, contributing to further structural transformation toward modern service-based
economies.
Information and knowledge, and their increased prevalence as the region has become
more connected, have played a key role in recent developments. Knowledge is non-
rivalrous, building potential links between international integration and growth. Grossman
and Helpman (2015) note that integration of peoples and cultures facilitates the flow of
knowledge across national borders and foreign ideas can prove useful for inventing or
improving products or production processes. Furthermore, integration of product markets
via international trade affords those who invent or improve products a greater potential
market in which to earn returns even as it subjects them to additional competition from
foreign rivals. Finally, international interactions affect the incentives for creation of new
knowledge as well as those for technological diffusion, with consequences for productivity
growth. Knowledge spillovers tend to accelerate growth, as a lower cost of further
innovation arises with advances made elsewhere.
Douglas H. Brooks Connectivityin East Asia
©2016 JapanCenter for EconomicResearch 177

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT