Comment on “The Southeast Asian Economies in the Age of Discontent”

AuthorChalongphob Sussangkarn
Published date01 July 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12310
Date01 July 2020
Comment on The Southeast Asian Economies
in the Age of Discontent
Chalongphob SUSSANGKARN
Thailand Development Research Institute
JEL codes: F02, F60, H12, Z18
Accepted: 15 February 2020
In recent years, one can see the emergence of a radically different economic policy par-
adigm, whose key characteristics include a rise of illiberalism, anti-globalization move-
ments, populism, economic nationalism and the emergence of democratically elected
authoritarian leaders, particularly President Donald Trump. Basri and Hill (2020) pro-
vide an excellent succinct review of the economic contexts that have led to the emer-
gence of these characteristics, which, thus far, seem to affect the advanced economies
more than developing economies. The main focus of Basri and Hill (2020) is on 5 Asso-
ciation of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) middle income economies, and the ques-
tion whether these economies may also slide toward illiberalism, and if not, what kind
of policies and reforms are needed to support these countriescontinued development.
In general, I agree with Basri and Hill that the ASEAN economies will not back-
track into illiberalism. ASEAN economies are mostly export oriented economies, so
they benet from open trade regimes. Extreme populism, economic nationalism and
elected authoritarian leaders are different. In Thailand, we have seen it all before.
The most widespread economic nationalism phase occurred as a result of the Asian
nancial crisis and the role of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). Through mone-
tary mismanagement, Thailand became insolvent in mid-1997 and had to enter an
IMF supervised program. While recovering from insolvency is bound to be painful,
critics of the IMF program pointed to a number of issues, such as the harsh nature of
the tight scal and monetary policies without due regard for social or political conse-
quences, imposition of full guarantees for creditors of nancial institutions, and the
imposition of relatively rapid (re sale type) structural reform measures. As it turned
out, the large depreciation of the Baht led to a rapid turnaround of the current
account. Foreign reserves rose quickly and by mid-1999 Thailand no longer needed to
make further drawings from the IMF package, and as a result, there was no need to
implement IMF conditionality. Thus, structural reforms measures were not fully
implemented, and in hindsight, given their controversial nature, it would have been
better not to have the structural reform conditionality. In any case, the Thai (and other
Correspondence: Chalongphob Sussangkarn, Thailand Development Research Institute, 565 Soi
Ramkhamhaeng 39, Wangthonglang District, Bangkok 10310, Thailand. Email: chalongp@tdri.or.th
212 © 2020 Japan Center for Economic Research
doi: 10.1111/aepr.12310 Asian Economic Policy Review (2020) 15, 212213

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT