Comment on “The Future of East Asia’s Trade: A Call for Better Globalization”

Published date01 July 2018
Date01 July 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12221
AuthorHal Hill
Comment on The Future of East Asias
Trade: A Call for Better Globalization
Hal HILL
Australian National University
JEL codes: F1, F13, F15, F16, F6
Accepted: 16 March 2018
There is much to admire and agree with in the stimulating and comprehensive paper by
Pangestu et al. (2018). Pangestu et al. maintain that the new normal,of an increasingly
open global economy, that has underpinned East Asias strong and successful export orien-
tation, is under serious threat. They also argue that Asia needs to respond not by a resort
to protectionism but by continuing to open up unilaterally and by playing a constructive
role in keeping the global system open.
On factors explaining the slowdown in trade, the authors refer to the slower growth in
both productivity and innovation. The patent data do support the authorscontention that
innovation is slowing down, yet some of the predictions of the ongoing information tech-
nology (IT) revolution, robotization, and so on suggest that these data may be an imperfect
proxy. Pangestu et al. also contend that the maturation of global value chains (GVC)
explains the slower trade growth. The intuition here is that major producers like China
have less need to source inputs from other countries as their industrial competence sprea ds
ever more widely. Incidentally, the GVC are measured by the proxy of trade in machine
goods. Other authors (e.g. Athukorala) have an alternative Standard International Trade
Classication (SITC) denition. It might be interesting to know whether the results are sen-
sitive to the latter denition of GVC.
Pangestu et al. argue that rising economic and political uncertainty is just as important, if
not more so, than rising protectionism. I suspect that the jury is still out on this issue, espe-
cially as Pangestu et al. show clearly that the resort to nontariff measures (NTM) since the
global nancial crisis has intensied. They caution that these NTM do not necessarilyindicate
rising protectionism. I would add the caveat that there are invariably protectionist interests
lurking behind (or gravitating to) calls for betterenvironmental or labor standards, and so on.
In their discussion on trade and inequality in Section 4, Pangestu et al. cite various studies
that globalization appears to be associated with rising intracountry (but not intercountry)
inequality.I would emphasize appearsas the key consideration is surely how open economies
are managed. That is, as Pangestu et al. rightly emphasize, it is the accompanying policies that
matter education and training, the tax system, social safety nets, geographic poverty traps,
and so on. This points to an argument that is now gathering global momentum, that the
Correspondence: Hal Hill, Arndt Corden Department of Economics, College of Asia and the
Pacic, The Australian National University, Canberra 2601, Australia. Email: hal.hill@anu.edu.au
© 2018 Japan Center for Economic Research 239
doi: 10.1111/aepr.12221 Asian Economic Policy Review (2018) 13, 239240

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT