Comment on “Public Pension Fund Management: Best Practice and International Experience”

Published date01 July 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12107
Date01 July 2015
AuthorPeter R. Orszag
Comment on “Public Pension Fund
Management: Best Practice and
International Experience”
Peter R. ORSZAG†
Citigroup and Bloomberg
JEL codes: F21, G11, G23, H55, J26
Rozanov (2015) makes two core points: first,that pension funds should be professionally
managed, and second that in practice the Canadian model of such management is attrac-
tive for multiple reasons. Except for those who would explicitly favor incompetence, the
first point is, I would think, relatively uncontroversial. So I would like to focus my com-
ments on the second point.
Before examining the performance of a public pension fund that has invested in
asset classes beyond bonds, it is important to revisit whether funds should be invested in
such assets in the first place. A classic examination of this issue in the context of private
pension funds is Bodie (1988); Broadbent et al. (2006) provide an updated summary of
the arguments. A key,lingering question is whether the higher expected return associated
with other asset classes justifies the additional risk (especially given the effect of interest
rate changes on the liability side of a pension fund; a bond portfolio on the asset side
provides a natural hedge). Rozanov correctly argues that this type of question needs to
be evaluated by each fund, according to its investment philosophy, and that pension
funds may have different perspectives on this question than endowments.1
A second, more problematic issue involves the comparison of returns on portfolios
with different weights assigned to various asset classes, which drives the policy recom-
mendation of following the Canadian model. Rozanov’s conclusions about the superior-
ity of the Canadian model relative to Norway rest heavily on Ambachtsheer (2012),
which is a four-page newsletter with little detail. Table 1 reproduces some of the data in
Ambachtsheer’s (2012) table.
Table 1 seems somewhat underwhelming, in and of itself, as the basis for declaring
that the Canadian model is a more compelling alternative to the Norway model. To be
sure, Rozanov updates the figures,as shown in table 3 of his paper. That update, however,
merely underscores the problems involved in the comparison.
First, it is challenging to construct an adequate benchmark portfolio for illiquid,
private investments, which have historically been more dominant in the Canadian
model. This is reflected in the much higher tracking errors for the Canadian portfolio.
The figures presented as “excess returns” are thus not directly comparable with one
another.
†Correspondence: Peter R. Orszag, Citigroup and Bloomberg, 388 Greenwich Street, New York,NY
10013. USA. Email: orszagp@gmail.com
bs_bs_banner
doi: 10.1111/aepr.12107 Asian Economic Policy Review (2015) 10, 296–298
© 2015 Japan Center for Economic Research296

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT