China's Overinvestment and International Trade Conflicts

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/cwe.12293
Published date01 September 2019
AuthorGunther Schnabl
Date01 September 2019
©2019 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
China & World Economy / 37–62, Vol. 27, No. 5, 2019
37
*Gunther Schnabl, Senior Fellow, Institute of Economic Policy, Leipzig University, Germany. Email:
schnabl@wifa.uni-leipzig.de. The author thanks Nils Sonnenberg and Tim Sepp for excellent research
assistance and the Friedrich August von Hayek Foundation for nancial support.
China’s Overinvestment and International
Trade Conicts
Gunther Schnabl*
Abstract
For a long time, China’s impressive growth performance has been driven by investment
and high productivity gains. Based on a discussion of possible overcapacities and
overinvestment in China, this paper investigates the sustainability of China’s investment
and export-driven growth model. Since the turn of the millennium, buoyant capital
inows and low interest rates have been at the root of overinvestment and misallocation
of capital, which necessitated export subsidies to clear markets. The overinvestment
boom is argued to have ended around 2014. Since then, the overcapacities have
weakened China’s bargaining position in the US–Chinese trade conflict and have
tempted Chinese authorities to postpone the restructuring of the Chinese economy by
providing low-interest credit. The gradual reemergence of quasi-soft budget constraints
is seen to undermine China’s long-term growth potential.
Key words: credit growth, overinvestment, rebalancing, soft budget constraints, trade policy,
zombication
JEL codes: E22, E43, E58, F13
I. Introduction
Given impressive growth performance, the literature has hailed China as the new global
economic hegemon. Fogel (2007) predicts that China’s GDP per capita will reach
US$85,000 by 2040, with the share in global GDP (40 percent) dwarfing the US (14
percent). It has been argued that the Chinese currency is challenging the leading role
of the dollar as an international currency (Prasad, 2018). By 2018, the real growth rate
of China was 6.6 percent, substantially above the US growth rate of 2.9 percent and far
beyond Japan, the largest Asian rival, at 1.1 percent.
While Chinese growth has remained high compared to industrialized countries, the
momentum has slowed, from 14.2 percent in 2007 to 6.3 percent in 2019, with ofcial
Gunther Schnabl / 37–62, Vol. 27, No. 5, 2019
©2019 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
38
numbers occasionally being put into question. At the same time, vulnerabilities have
emerged. Concerns about overcapacities in industrial production (European Chamber,
2016) have triggered a discussion about rebalancing the Chinese economy toward
domestically oriented, consumption-based growth (Fukumoto and Muto, 2012; Yu,
2012; Zhang, 2016).1 Glaeser et al. (2017) identied the potential for an unsustainable
real estate bubble.
From an international perspective, the Chinese current account surplus, in particular
versus the US, has been regarded as unfair (Bergsten, 2010) and has been used by the
US government as a justification to impose punitive tariffs, thereby risking a trade
war and putting the international free trade system at risk (Ha and Deng, 2019). Given
accelerating capital outows from China, takeovers of enterprises in the industrialized,
emerging and developing countries are increasingly understood as economic
colonialization. At the same time, the global slowdown of growth makes China’s
investment in developing countries and emerging markets look risky (Page, 2019).
To evaluate the growth perspectives and bargaining position in the trade conflict
with the US, this paper scrutinizes potential overinvestment in China from a theoretical
perspective. In contrast to previous papers, which have analyzed the role of investment
for Chinese growth empirically (Zhang, 2003; Wang and Hu, 2007; Ahuja and Nabar,
2012), the focus of this paper is on the build-up of overcapacities in the industrial sector,
their repercussions on growth and the adequate policy response.
II. Investment, Growth and Economic Catch-up
Like Japan and other East Asian countries, the economic catch-up process in China
has been based on industrial production and exports to the prosperous markets of the
industrialized economies (export-led growth). The upgrading of capital stock and the
technological level of industrial production is at the root of increasing productivity and
real wage increases (Solow, 1956; Swan, 1956; Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964). Yet
macroeconomic stability and an efcient allocation of capital are prerequisites for the
positive impact of investment on growth (McKinnon, 1973).
1. Microeconomic Reforms and Macroeconomic Stabilization
The catch-up process in China is based on market-oriented reforms initiated by Deng
Xiaoping in the 1970s (Chang, 1988). During the first stage in the 1970s and 1980s,
1Zhang (2016) distinguishes four dimensions of rebalancing: external, internal, environmental and
distributional. This paper focuses on the rst two dimensions.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT