Can cooperative game theory solve the low‐risk puzzle?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1696
AuthorTobias Hiller,Benjamin R. Auer
Published date01 April 2019
Date01 April 2019
Received: 21 February 2018 Revised: 25 July 2018 Accepted: 10 September 2018
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1696
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Can cooperative game theory solve the low-risk puzzle?
Benjamin R. Auer1,2,3 Tobias Hiller3
1Brandenburg University of Technology
Cottbus-Senftenberg, Chair of Finance,
Cottbus, Germany
2Research Network Area Macro, Money
and International Finance, CESifo
Munich, Munich, Germany
3Departments of Finance and
Microeconomics, University of Leipzig,
Leipzig, Germany
Correspondence
Benjamin R. Auer,Chair of Finance,
Brandenburg University of Technology
Cottbus-Senftenberg, Erich-Weinert-Str. 1,
03046 Cottbus, Germany.
Email: auer@b-tu.de
JEL Classification: G10; G11; C71
Abstract
In this article, we illustrate that cooperative game theory may havethe potential
to solve the low-risk puzzle, which has become one of the most important in
modern finance because its implication of a negative risk-return trade-off poses a
challenge to traditional models of asset prices. Using several simulation settings,
we highlight that quantifying risk by means of assets' Shapley values, that is,
assets' contributions to overall portfolio risk, instead of classic measures supplies
a (more) positive risk-return relationship in manypractically relevant cases. This
is partially attributable to the fact that the game-theoretic risk measure captures
more investment-relevant information than commonly used alternatives.
KEYWORDS
cooperative game theory, low-risk puzzle, Shapley value
1INTRODUCTION
Empirical research has revealed an effect in the cross
section of asset returns, which is now known as the
low-risk puzzle. According to this phenomenon, invest-
ment opportunities with low risk consistently tend to out-
perform their high-risk counterparts (see Ang et al., 2006,
2009; Dutt and Humphery-Jenner,2013; Frazzini and Ped-
ersen, 2014). Because it holds across different markets and
asset classes and seriously challenges asset pricing theo-
ry's traditional notion of a positive risk-return trade-off,
thelow-riskpuzzleisconsideredtobeoneofthemost
important capital market anomalies discovered so far.
Although many authors have tried to explain the puz-
zle in the context of restricted borrowing, preferences for
assets with lottery-like payoffs, or fund managers' man-
dates to beat fixed benchmarks (see Blitz et al., 2014), a
more straightforward rationale might be that researchers
are simply using “the wrong measure of risk” (see Baker
et al., 2011, p. 43). Previous studies have relied on the stan-
dard deviation of returns (see Dutt and Humphery-Jenner,
2013), idiosyncratic volatility (see Ang et al., 2006), or beta
(see Frazzini and Pedersen, 2014) to document the puzzle
and to point out its relevance for investors.1Inother words,
they have shown that these measures produce risk rank-
ings of individual assets that are inconsistent with the idea
that investors should be rewarded for bearing risk. How-
ever, all these measures have serious limitations because
they do not fully capture the risk that is actually relevant
for typical investment decisions and/or because they are
bound to restrictive theoretical assumptions. For example,
measures of total risk (such as the standard deviation) treat
risk in an isolated fashion and thus do not consider poten-
tial diversification benefits in a portfolio context. Further-
more, popular measures of systematic risk (such as beta)
can cover diversification issues (see Fama and French,
2004) but are bound to an unobservable market portfolio
(see Roll, 1977), which is not held by most investors (see
De Bondt, 1998). In other words, they capture how an asset
contributes to the risk of a portfolio that is not relevant
from a practical perspective.
We argue that a measure of risk, which can be derived
from cooperative game theory, has the potential to solve
the low-risk puzzle. We suggest ranking assets based on
their Shapley (1953) contribution to the risk of an invest-
ment portfolio. This is because the process of portfolio
884 © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe IntJ Fin Econ. 2019;24:884–889.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT